:::

詳目顯示

回上一頁
題名:論中共政權與新興資本家的關係
作者:楊穎超
作者(外文):Ying-Chao Yang
校院名稱:國立臺灣大學
系所名稱:國家發展研究所
指導教授:吳玉山
周繼祥
學位類別:博士
出版日期:2009
主題關鍵詞:私營企業現代化理論關係民主化資產階級democratizationguan-ximodernization paradigmbourgeoisieprivate enterprises owner
原始連結:連回原系統網址new window
相關次數:
  • 被引用次數被引用次數:期刊(1) 博士論文(0) 專書(0) 專書論文(0)
  • 排除自我引用排除自我引用:0
  • 共同引用共同引用:0
  • 點閱點閱:38
本文以關係討論中共政權對新興資產階級的控制。過去對資產階級與中共政權互動的討論,大約可分為受現代化理論影響的「民主樂觀說」,以及從現實演進出發的「威權穩定說」兩者。第一種民主樂觀說認為在資產階級逐漸變強的前提下,雙方相互競合對彼方的影響,因此資產階級不是目前正在侵蝕中共的統治,就是企圖於未來推翻威權政府;第二種威權穩定說則是認為在中共統治能力不斷提昇的前提下,懷疑資產階級能扮演的角色,他們若非認為中共控制或吸納了資產階級,就是推定雙方暫時互利合作。
以上論述皆隱含一個共同假設:中共政權與私營企業主雙方皆是獨立於彼此之外的個體,按照不同力量對比的邏輯展開競爭與合作。本文認為,區分了我與他群的不同,容易推論出兩群的對立或控制。但如果兩者實二而一,如此假設只會誤導我們找尋答案的方向。因此本文提出另一種假設:新興的資產階級其實脫胎於中共政權內部。並於第二章運用一個重要變數:關係的建構及發展來回答這個問題。在第三章我們是這樣論證的:首先是社會主義意識型態的獨尊之勢,造成了政治運動與計畫經濟體制橫掃一切資本主義因子,當然也包括被視為剝削者的資產階級。而在計畫經濟體制的缺憾下,關係成為社會中稀缺資源的配置制度,而掌控資源者,非共黨官僚莫屬。
經改開始後,資源的配置制度雖加入了市場的運作,但這個市場卻非西方理論家所想像的市場。我們有兩個面向的觀察:第一是如何創業,其次則是如何經營以面對商業競爭及政治(政策)壓力的問題。在創業方面,經濟學教科書告訴我們,土地、勞力、資本乃是市場經濟生產產品的關鍵,而經改初期一般平民根本沒有這三個要素,如何完成初步的資本累積成為所有私營業主的共同困境,開業之後他們並需面對「非國有」之鄉鎮企業的競爭、以及無所不在的政治壓力;而在計畫體制漸進至市場改革的發展策略下,統制經濟多如牛毛的規定不可能一夕廢止,法規運用憑乎官員一心。
在此種環境下脫穎而出的唯一方法,依本文之見非關係莫屬:沒有關係時,私有企業經營者首先便要面臨如何憑空變出生產要素的問題,當貨物產出時,便要面對其他有硬預算壓力、資本亦較之雄厚的鄉鎮企業對手競爭,而在結構限制下,還要小心受意識型態影響之中共官員打擊;反之「私營」企業主們則可擁有生產要素,甚而直接併入競爭對手(鄉鎮企業),也不用擔心官員的打壓。
為了要檢驗推論,本文第四章第三節對私營企業主的背景資料進行調查,企圖釐清幾件事:
第一、 既然私營企業主要與中共官方有關係才能發展,那麼領先群倫的中共富豪應該要有相當比例佔據黨政職位,才能證明本文的推論為真;
第二、 以西方經驗看來,現代化引起了階級及所有新生集體的意識,並產生政治覺悟,因此推派代理人爭取政治權利。過去中國大陸的歷史經驗已經看出資產階級政治權利與日俱進的趨勢,相對於此則是中共過去堅持的意識型態步步退縮。那麼該階級是否出現了夠份量的代表?如否,我們便能推論出,關係在此發揮了隱身幕後的效果。
為此,本文調查了「中國富豪榜前一百名之私營企業主」背景、具有企業主背景的中共候補中央委員及中華全國工商業聯合會第一到第十屆領導階層背景資料。本文發現,由富比士雜誌選出的2002年前一百名中國大陸富豪中,找不到官方背景或聯繫者只有七人。可知中國大陸的百大富豪中,百分之九十以上都與中共官方有關係。
而在第二個推論上,本文羅列經改以來中共促進私營經濟發展的重要論述內容,發現私營企業的地位與利益在中共過去最重視的意識型態領域與憲法層次中逐步彰顯,那麼是否其代表佔有顯要的政治地位呢?在中共中央候補委員的企業代表及中華全國工商業聯合會第一到第十屆領導階層背景資料中可以看出,私營企業主在中共的黨內地位並無提高趨勢,那麼究竟是什麼力量促成私營企業主的節節勝利?本文認為目前所有的證據都指向關係發揮了作用,才使得私營企業主們得以在沒有檯面代表的前提下,默默推動其政治利益提昇。而這種關係的建構必須是在改革前就已奠下基礎,到了改革後充分發揮,才能同時達到如此隱匿又豐碩的成果。因此我們可以下一個結論:1979年後產生的私營企業主們與中共官方根本是系出同源,而非兩個不同群體,所以才能在代表不顯的情形下,逐步使得中共放鬆其過去宣稱關鍵的意識型態領域,而私營企業主也很自然的配合了中共的統治。故從利益角度看來,關係的確順利的融合了中共及私營企業主。
This thesis argues that the government of the People Republic of China (PRC) controls the owners of private enterprises through guanxi. In the past, there were two explanations of the interaction between the PRC government and the bourgeoisie class. One was the “democracy" doctrine, which was influenced by the modernization paradigm. The other was the “regime stability” doctrine, which is based upon the PRC’s recent political development. The former argues that the PRC authority and the bourgeoisie compete against each other for power. According to this presupposition, the bourgeoisie class is growing under capitalism, thus, the bourgeoisie will either usurp the regime power now or will overthrow the PRC regime in the near future. The latter focuses on the regime’s flexible control and argues that the Communist Party of China (CPC) can keep control of their authoritarian regime rule.
Scholars have debated the above arguments, and conducted surveys to prove the validity of their claims. However, both arguments contain the same basic hypothesis: the PRC government and the bourgeoisie are two distinct entities. As they cooperate and compete with each other, their subsequent power grows and declines. The reason for their conflict lies in the fact they are two opposing and separate groups. It would be simple for us to assume this is the only reason for the conflict between the PRC government and the bourgeoisie. However, if in fact the PRC authority and bourgeoisie are actually the same group, this would greatly undermine this hypothesis. Therefore, this paper has another hypothesis: the newborn bourgeoisie in mainland China emerged from the CPC. The reasoning for this hypothesis is that the CPC has taken a different path from the fate of pre-socialism countries in East European since 1988. In comparison to many “the third way” examples, the newly emerging bourgeoisie class in mainland China are relatively subdued, in that we can not see any organized potential opposition to the authoritarian regime. Many scholars comment that the CPC’s control is comprehensive and efficient; however, these scholars have yet to answer a simple question: most authoritarian regimes, which used similar control skills, could not resist the pressure of capitalism, but how has the CPC government been able to keep its rule until now? A possible explanation is that because the newborn bourgeoisie class in mainland China actually is born of the CPC, the relationship between newborn bourgeoisie and the CPC government works in cooperation rather than through control and confrontation.
This thesis uses “guanxi” to answer the question of how the CPC government has been able to retain control. Chapter two discusses the context of guanxi, and then chapter three will point out how mainland China’s political and economic environment has made guanxi, an important institution of resource exchange. In this political and economic environment, the CPC government purged everything related to capitalism, including the bourgeoisie, through political movements and planned economy. Although the CPC government discarded the traditional system based upon families and land relation, the CPC then restructured the relationship between people in a new way to distribute resources, guanxi was this new way.
After 1978, the economic reform started and state power withdrew from society. A new way in which to distribute resources emerged: the market. Through the capitalist market system, people believed the bourgeoisie could eventually compete with the authoritarian regime.
However, the market has not developed in the PRC the way that some scholars had imagined. Two important questions to answer are: how did a regular person start an enterprise in the early reform years? And how did the private enterprise owners deal with competition and political pressure? Any economic textbook will explain that land, labor and capital are the basis of production. However, according to the PRC official data, most average individuals in mainland China lacked all three in the early 1980’s. Where did the necessary production resources come from? In addition, after building enterprises, the owners would compete with other “non state-own enterprises” which included township and village enterprises (TVEs) and always were under the political pressure.
The best way private enterprise owners to succeed in this environment, according to this thesis, is through the use of guanxi: by guanxi, private enterprise owners made friends with officials and thus could obtain loans, land and labor. They were able to compete against TVEs, who even bought those TVEs by local government help without capital. All problems could be readily solved through guanxi.
In order to exam these inference, chapter three and four cite the first hand data, which was conducted by PRC officials and scholars to demonstrate the lack of these three elements, the competence of TVEs, and the pressure of political movements. At the same time, we also investigate the background of some important private enterprise owners to examine the following hypotheses:
Firstly, if the bourgeoisie must cooperate with the CPC, in order to run their enterprises smoothly, then we should see that the bourgeois occupy offices in the regime.
Secondly, if the bourgeois did not occupy the CPC core then, according to the modernization paradigm, we should see all social classes (including the bourgeoisie) within a country shape their own consensus, and in turn support the delegates who fight for their political rights. On the contrary, if there are not the bourgeoisie delegates within the CPC core but the political rights for the bourgeoisie are still growing, we can infer that there may be some unofficial bourgeoisie delegates within the CPC core. The reason is that the CPC ideology, which is socialism, absolutely refutes capitalism, the ideology of the bourgeois. In order to retain its legitimacy, the CPC should have limited the bourgeoisie’s political rights, even if the CPC still approves of the bourgeoisie running their enterprises. However, the fact is that the political rights for the bourgeoisie are also growing; that is, the CPC ideology is declining. How can the bourgeoisie improve their position if there are no delegates within the CPC core to support them? The existence of guanxi is the only possible answer.
Therefore, this thesis investigates the background of the 100 richest Chinese chosen in 2002 by Forbes Magazine, the CPC alternate members who also represent private enterprises, and the leadership of the All-China Federation of Industry & Commerce (ACFIC) from first to tenth term. First of all, among the 100 richest Chinese, we find only seven individuals on the list who do not have a connection to the CPC. In other words, over 90% of the richest Chinese are connected to the CPC regime.
Next, this thesis lists the most important PRC official statements regarding the improvement and development of private enterprises. From those statements, the growing trend towards the bourgeoisie interests in context of the CPC ideology and the PRC Constitution is evident. So do the bourgeoisie delegates occupy positions in the CPC core? From the backgrounds of the CPC alternate members who also represent enterprises, and the leadership of ACFIC, we find that private owners do not occupy the top leadership position in ACFIC, which is called a “bridge” between the CPC and owners. Furthermore, the organization’s political influence has not increased within the CPC. Therefore, how could the bourgeoisie improve their political rights? All evidence points to the influence of guanxi, because through guanxi, the bourgeoisie could quietly push their rights rather than fighting to elect favorable political delegates. The conclusion is that the origin of the PRC and its bourgeoisie class are the same thing instead of two distinct groups. This is why the CPC is able to incrementally move away from its original ideology, because their control is safe from the bourgeoisie competition. Therefore, CPC cooperates with the bourgeoisie through the use of guanxi in the PRC.
中文部份
一、專書
《馬克斯恩格斯選集》第一卷,1972,北京:人民出版社。
《馬克斯恩格斯選集》第一卷,1995,北京:人民出版社。
Francis Fukuyama,李永熾譯,民83,《歷史之終結與最後一人》,台北:時報文化。
Joseph E. Stiglitz,李明譯,2002,《全球化的許諾與失落》,台北:大塊。
Philippe C. Schimitter,1997,〈民間社會與民主的鞏固〉,《鞏固第三波民主》,台北:業強。
Samuel P. Huntington著,王冠華等譯,1988,《變動社會的政治秩序》,北京:三聯。
Samuel P. Huntington著,劉軍寧譯,民83,《第三波:二十世紀末的民主浪潮》,台北:五南。
丁學良,1994,《共產主義後與中國》,香港:牛津。
中共中央文獻研究室,1993,《建國以來重要文獻選編》,北京:中央文獻出版社。
中華全國工商業聯合會編,2007,《1993-2006中國私營企業大型調查》,北京:中華工商聯合出版社。
毛澤東,1991,《毛澤東選集》,第一卷,北京:人民出版社。
毛澤東,1991,《毛澤東選集》,第五卷,北京:人民出版社。
王小強,《摸著石頭過河:中國改革之路》,香港:牛津出版社。
王信賢,2006,《爭辯中的中國社會組織研究:「國家-社會關係的視角」》,台北:韋伯。new window
王紹光,〈破除對Civil Society的迷思〉,周雪光編,《當代中國的國家與社會》(台北:桂冠,1992),頁3-27。
田凱,2004,《非協調約束與組織運作—中國慈善組織與政府關係的個案研究》,北京:商務印書館。
全國工商聯研究室、國家發改委中小企業司、國務院研究室工交貿易司編,2006,《創造公平競爭的法治環境、政策環境、市場環境》,北京:中華工商聯合出版社。
何思因、陳德昇、耿曙主編,2003,《中國大陸硏究方法與成果》,臺北 : 政大國關中心。
何清漣,2001,《中國的陷阱》,香港:明鏡出版社,二版。
吳玉山,民84,《共產世界的變遷:四個共產政權的比較》,台北:東大。
吳玉山,民85,《遠離社會主義:中國大陸、蘇聯和波蘭的經濟轉型》,台北:正中。new window
呂亞力,民97,《政治學:從權力角度之政治剖析》,台北:台灣東華。
李英明,2003,《閱讀中國:政策、權力與意識型態的辯證》,台北:生智。
李強,2004,《轉型時期中國社會分層》,瀋陽:遼寧教育出版社。
李路路、李漢林,2000,《中國的單位組織:資源、權力與交換》,杭州:浙江人民出版社。
周立群等主編,2001,《中小企業改革與發展研究》,北京:人民出版社。
周繼祥,民93,《中共全國人民代表大會與民主化之研究》,台北:行政院大陸委員會委託研究計劃案。
林佳龍、鄭永年編,2001,《民族主義與兩岸關係》,台北:新自然主義。
林毅夫、蔡昉、李周,1995,《中國的奇蹟:發展戰略與經濟改革》,香港:中文大學出版社。
洪美蘭著,2002,《經濟激進轉型策略—中東歐之經驗與啟示》,台北:翰蘆。
凌志軍,2007,《中國的新革命》,北京:新華。
凌志軍,2007,《中國的新革命》,北京:新華出版社。
庫恩(Kuhn, R. L.)著,談崢等譯,2005,《他改變了中國:江澤民傳》,上海:上海譯文出版社。
徐斯儉、吳玉山編,民96,《黨國蛻變—中共政權的菁英與政策》,台北:五南。new window
徐瑞希,民80,《政商關係解讀:台灣企業實用政治學入門》,台北:遠流。
馬立誠,2005,《大突破》,北京:中華工商聯合出版社。
國家「七五」期間中國私營經濟研究課題組編,1989,《中國的私營經濟—現狀、問題、前景》,北京:中國社會科學出版社。
國家人事局編,1988,《人事工作文件選編》(第十九卷),北京:勞動人事出版社。
國家統計局農村社會經濟調查司編,2006,《中國農村貧困監測報告》,北京:中國統計出版社。
寇健文,2004,《中共精英政治的演變:制度化與權力移轉,1978-2004》,台北:五南。
康曉光,2005,《仁政》,新加坡:八方文化。
張厚義、明立志主編,1999,《中國私營企業發展報告No.1(1978~1998)》,北京:社會科學文獻出版社。
張厚義、明立志編,2000,《中國私營企業發展報告(1999)》,北京:社會科學文獻出版社。
張清溪等,1995,《經濟學理論與實際》,台北:翰蘆。
陳永發,1998,《中國共產革命七十年》,台北:聯經。new window
陳生洛,2004,《中國國有企業的產權變革與黨的領導》,台北:韋伯。
陳凌等著,2007,《制度與能力:中國民營企業20年成長的解析》,上海:上海人民出版社。
喬健主編,1998,《社會科學的應用與中國現代化》,高雄:麗文文化。
項懷誠,1993,《中國:市場經濟與宏觀調控》,北京:中國財政經濟出版社。
黃仁宇,1994,《從大歷史角度看蔣介石日記》,台北:時報。
黃仁宇,2004,《大歷史不會萎縮》,桂林:廣西師範大學出版社。
楊光斌,2003,《中國經濟轉型中的國家權力》,北京:當代世界出版社。
楊繼繩,2004,《中國改革年代的政治鬥爭》,H.K.: Excellent Culture Press。
經濟社會體制比較編輯部編,1993,《腐敗:權力與金錢的交換》,北京:中國經濟出版社。
鄒讜,1994,《二十世紀中國政治:從宏觀歷史與微觀行動的角度看》,香港:牛津大學出版社。
裴敏欣,1997,〈匍匐前行的中國民主化〉,田弘茂、朱雲漢、Larry Diamond、MrcPlattner(編),《新興民主國家的機遇與挑戰》,台北:業強,頁374-398。
裴敏欣主編,2004,《中南海的選擇》,新加坡:八方。
趙乃斌、朱曉中主編,1995,《東歐經濟大轉軌》,北京:中國經濟出版社。
趙麗江,2006,《中國私營企業家的政治參與》,北京:中國經濟出版社。
齊墨編,民80,《新權威主義:對中國大陸未來命運的論爭》,台北:唐山。
劉兆佳等編,2000,《市場、階級與政治:變遷中的華人社會》,香港:香港中文大學香港亞太研究所。
劉國光、王洛林、李京文編,2002,《2003年:中國經濟形勢分析與預測》,北京:社會科學文獻出版社。
劉鴻雁,2006,《黃光裕傳奇:國美商戰實錄》,北京:華夏。
潘維,2002,〈民主迷信與中國政體改革的方向〉,朱雲漢等編,《華人社會政治學本土化研究的理論與實踐》,台北:桂冠,頁309-356。
鄭永年,民89,《政治漸進主義:中國的政治改革和民主化前景》,台北:吉虹。new window
盧漢龍主編,2004,《慈愛:關愛與和諧》,上海:上海社科院出版社。
戴園晨主編,2005,《中國經濟的奇蹟》,北京:人民出版社。
薄一波,1993,《若干重大決策與事件的回顧》,北京:中共中央黨校出版社。
譚慶剛,2007,《雙重轉型中的鄉鎮企業》,北京:社會科學文獻出版社。
二、期刊論文
方孝謙,民86,〈蘇南、溫州鄉鎮企業的研究現況:三種途徑的比較〉,《中國大陸研究》,40(2):34-52。new window
王信賢,2002,〈缺乏發展的增長:中國股票市場的制度內捲化〉,《中國大陸研究》,第45卷第4期(7月),頁43-74。new window
江迅,2007,〈胡錦濤警告諸侯中共面臨管治危機〉,《亞洲週刊》,12月23日,頁32-36。
吳玉山,民87,〈現代化理論vs. 政權穩定論:中國大陸民主發展的前景〉,《政治科學論叢》,9:443-464。new window
黃德北,2007,〈中國大陸資本主義發展與資本家之研究〉,《東亞研究》,38(2):1-43。new window
楊穎超,2004,〈(後)社會主義國家經改策略的政治選擇:以中國大陸、波蘭、匈牙利為例〉,《國家發展研究》,3(1):73-98。new window
楊穎超,2007,〈現代化典範與中共民主前景:第四條道路〉,《政治科學論叢》,33:151-192。new window
鄭永年、吳國光,1994,〈論中央—地方關係:中國制度轉型中的一個軸心問題〉,《當代中國研究》,第6期,總第45期,頁4-121。
黎安友,柯洛漪譯,2006,〈停滯的當下:中國發展陷入泥沼?〉,《當代中國研究通訊》,第7期,頁18-21。
燕清、董國禮,2005,《影子選舉:河灣村村委會選舉觀察》,引自周曉虹、謝曙光主編,《中國研究》,2005年秋季卷,總第2期,頁106-130。
羅卡(Jean-Louis Rocca),2005,〈知識的力量:穩定成長時期中國中產階層意象的建構〉,引自周曉虹、謝曙光主編,《中國研究》,2005年秋季卷,總第2期,頁74-83。
羅冠中,2008,〈中國首富黃光裕二度被查〉,《亞洲週刊》,12月14日,頁38-39。
邊燕杰、張展新,〈中國城市精英與收入差異:1988-1995〉,引自周曉虹、謝曙光主編,《中國研究》,2005年秋季卷,總第2期,頁1-18。
三、研討會論文
王信賢,2005,〈分裂統治下的市場中介組織:當代中國「國家—社會」關係新詮〉,「中共政權變遷:菁英、體制與政策學術研討會」(11月19日),台北:中研院政研所。
吳玉山,民92,〈中國大陸經濟改革總體策略之研究〉,台北:「中國大陸研究方法與成果」研討會論文。
楊穎超,2007,〈市場社會主義中的市場:中國大陸的例子〉,「2007兩岸關係與大陸研究」研究生論文研討會論文(5月26日),台北:行政院陸委會。
四、學位論文
鄒歷安,2003,《經濟發展的制度性解釋:私有化VS. 市場化》,台北:台大城鄉所碩士論文。
廖尉君,2005,《東亞奇蹟或危機—發展國家與新古典理論的爭辯》,台北:台大政研所碩士論文。
五、網路資料
〈中共中央關於1984年農村工作的通知〉,《中國網》http://www.china.com.cn/aboutchina/data/zgncggkf30n/2008-04/09/content_14685167.htm(2008/12/30查閱)
〈中國歷年外匯儲備〉,《中共國家外匯管理局》官方網站http://www.safe.gov.cn/model_safe/index.html (2008/12/31查閱)
〈民主法治週刊〉,《人民網》http://npc.people.com.cn/BIG5/28320/41246/48570/5627644.html(2008/10/26查閱)
《北京市工商局網上工作平臺》,http://www.hd315.gov.cn/gcs/19qu/pinggu/flfg/law_gsf.htm(2007/03/17查閱)
〈年廣九:鄧小平三次相救的「傻子」〉,《和訊網》, http://news.hexun.com/2008/nianguangjiu/index.html (2008/11/4查閱)
毛澤東,〈在中國共產黨第七屆中央委員會第二次全體會議上的報告〉,《中文馬克斯主義文庫》http://www.marxists.org/chinese/17/marxist.org-chinese-mao-19490305.htm (2009/1/5查閱)
毛澤東,〈為爭取國家財政經濟狀況的基本好轉而鬥爭〉,《中文馬克斯主義文庫》http://www.marxists.org/chinese/17/marxist.org-chinese-mao-19500606.htm (2008/6/25查閱)
毛澤東,〈黨在過渡時期的總路線〉,《中文馬克斯主義文庫》http://www.marxists.org/chinese/17/marxist.org-chinese-mao-195308.htm (2008/12/31查閱)
列寧,〈國家與革命〉,《中文馬克斯主義文庫》http://www.marxists.org/chinese/03/17.htm(2008/12/30查閱)
杜亮、劉亞洲,2003,《中國企業家》,11期,http://www.cnki.com.cn/Article/CJFDTotal-ZGQY200311036.htm (2008/12/31查閱)
蕭功秦,2004,〈中國後全能型的權威政治:發展中的優勢與問題〉《中國選舉與治理網》:http://www.chinaelections.org/NewsInfo.asp?NewsID=59341 (2007/11/19查閱)

英文部份
1.Books
Anderson, L. 1999. Transitions to Democracy. N.Y.: Columbia University Press.
Chan, Chih-jou Jay. 1999. “Local Institutions and the Transformation of Property Rights in Southern Fujian.” In Jean Oi and Andrew G. Walder. eds. Property Rights and Economic Reform in China. Stanford: Stanford University Press.
Chirot, Daniel. 1991. “What Happened in Eastern Europe in 1989?” in Daniel Chriot ed. The Crisis of Leninism and the Decline of the Left. Seattle: University of Washington Press. pp. 3-31.
Dickson, Bruce J. 2003. Red Capitalists in China. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Friedman, Edward and Barrett L. McCormick. 2000. What If China Doesn’t Democratize? N.Y.: M.E.Sharpe.
Fukuyama, Francis. 2002. The End of History and the Last Man N. Y.: Perennial.
Glassman, Ronald. 1991. China in Transition: Communism, capitalism, and Democracy. N.Y.: Praeger.
Harding, Harry. 1978. China’s Second Revolution: Reform after Mao. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.
Hsueh, Li-min, Chen-kuo Hsu, and Dwight H. Perkins eds. 2001. Industrialization and the State: The Changing Role of the Taiwan Government in the Economy, 1945-1998. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.
Huntington, Samuel P. 1991. The Third Wave: Democratization in the Late Twentieth Century. Norman: University of Oklahoma Press.
Huntington, Samuel P. 1996. Political Order in Changing Societies. New Haven: Yale University Press.
Janos, Andrew C. 1986. Politics and Paradigms: Changing Theories of Change in Social Science. Stanford: Stanford University Press.
Kautsky, John H. 1972. The Political Consequences of Modernization. N.Y.: John Wiley and Sons.
Kornai, Janos. 1989. “The Hungarian Reform Process: Vision, Hope, and Reality.” In Victor Nee and David Stark eds. Remarking the Economic Institution of Socialism: China and Eastern Europe. Stanford: Stanford University Press.
Kornai, Janos. 1992. The Socialist System: The Political Economy of Communism. Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press.
Lewin, Moshe. 1991. The Gorbachev Phenomenon: A Historical Interpretation. Berkeley: University of California Press.
Linz, Juan & Alfred Stepan. 1996. Problems of Democratic Transition & Consolidation. Baltimore: John Hopkins University Press.
Linz, Juan J. 2000. Totalitarian and Authoritarian Regimes. Boulder: Lynne Rienner.
Lowenthal, Richard. 1970. “Development vs. Utopia in Communist Policy.” In Chalmers Johnson. ed. Change in Communist Systems. Stanford: Stanford University Press.
McKinnon, Ronald I. 1994. “Gradual versus Rapid Liberalization in Socialist Economics,” in Proceedings of the World Bank Annual Conference on Development Economics. Washington, D.C.: The World Bank.
Moore, Barrington. 1966. Social Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy: Lord and Peasant in the Making of Modern World. Boston: Beacon Press.
Naughton, Barry J. 2004. The Western Development Program, in Barry J. Naughton and Dali Yang, eds., Holding China Together: Diversity and National Integration in the Post-Deng Era. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Pei, Minxin. 2006. China’s Trapped Transition: The Limits of Developmental Autocracy. Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard University Press.
Perry, Elizabeth. 1991. “Intellectuals and Tiananmen: Historical Perspective on an Aborted Revolution.” In Daniel Chirot, ed., the Crisis of Leninism and the Decline of the Left. Seattle: University of Washington Press. pp. 129-146.
Przeworski, Adam. 1991. Democracy and the Market: Political and Economic Reform in Eastern Europe and Latin America. N.Y.: Cambridge University Press.
Schurmann, Franz. 1966. Ideology and Organization in Communist China. Berkeley: University of California Press.
Solinger, Dorothy J. 1993. China’s Transition from Socialism: Statist Legacies and Marketing Reforms. Armonk: M. E. Sharpe.
Teiwes, Frederick C. 2002. “Normal Politics with Chinese Characteristics,” in Jonathan Unger ed., The Nature of Chinese Politics: From Mao to Jiang. Armonk, N.Y.: M.E. Sharpe.
Walder, Andrew. ed. 1995. The Waning of the Communist State: Economic Origins of Political Decline in China and Hungary. Berkeley: University of California Press.
Wang, Yanlai. 2003. China’s Economic Development and Democratization. Aldershot, Hants, England: Ashgate.
Wank, David L. 1999. Commodifying Communism: Business, Trust, and Politics in a Chinese City. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Weber, M. 1946. Class, Status, and Party. In H. H. Gerth(ed.) & C. Wright Mills (ed. & Trans.) From Max Weber: Essay in Sociology. N.Y.: Oxford University Press, pp.180-195.
White, Gordon. 1993. Riding the Tiger: The Politics of Economic Reform in Post-Mao China. Stanford: Stanford University Press.
World Bank. 1998. China 2020. N.Y.: Oxford University Press.
2.Journal Articles
Bian, Y. and J. Logan. 1996. “Market Transition and the Persistence of Power: The Changing Stratification System in Urban China,” American Sociological Review 61: 739-758.
Brzezinski, Zbigniew. 1998. “Disruption without Disintegration,” Journal of Democracy 9(1): 4-64.
Crawford, E. S. & Elinor Ostrom.1995. A Grammar of Institutions,” American Political Science Review, vol. 89, no. 3 (September), pp. 582-600.
Gallagher, Mary E. 2002 . “Reform and Openness: Why China’s Economic Reforms Have Delayed Democracy,” World Politics 54(3), (April): 338-372.
Harding, Harry. 1998. “The Halting Advance of Pluralism,” Journal of Democracy 9(1): 11-17.
Helliwell, John. 1994. “Empirical Linkages between Democracy and Economic Growth,” British Journal of Political Science 24(2): 22-48.
Huber, Evelyne, Dietrich Rueschemeyer, and John D. Stephens. 1993. “The Impact of Economic Development and Democracy,” Journal of Economic Perspectives 7(3): 71-85.
Huntington, Samuel P. 1984. “Will More Countries Become Democratic?” Political Science Quarterly 99(2): 193-218
Krugman, Paul. 1994. “The Myth of Asia’s Miracle,” Foreign Affairs, vol.73, no. 6, pp.62-78.
Landman, Todd. 1999. “Economic Development and Democracy: the View from Latin America,” Political Studies 47(4): 607-626.
Lee, Keun, Donghoon Hahn, and Justin Lin. 2002. “Is China Following the East Asian Model? A Comparative Institutional Analysis,” The China Review, vol.2, no. 1(Spring), pp. 85-120.
Li, Cheng. 2005. “Hu’s Policy Shift and the Tuanpai’s Coming-of Age,” China Leadership Monitor, No. 15(Summer).
Lipset, Seymour Martin. 1994 . “The Social Requisites of Democracy Revisited,” American Sociological Review 59: 1-22.
Lipset, Seymour Martin, Kyoung-Ryung Seong, and John Charles Torres. 1993. “A Comparative Analysis of the Social Requisites of Democracy,” International Social Science Journal 45(May): 155-175.
Nathan, Andrew J. 1998. “Even Our Caution Must be Hedged,” Journal of Democracy 9(1): 60-64.
Nathan, Andrew J. 2003. “Authoritarian Resilience,” Journal of Democracy 14(1): 6-17.
Nee, V. 1989. “A Theory of Market Transition: From Redistribution to Markets in State Socialism,” American Sociological Review 54: 663-681
Nee, V. 1991. “Social Inequalities in Reforming State Socialism: Between Redistribution and Markets in China,” American Sociological Review 56: 267-282.
Oksenberg, Michel. 1998. “Confronting A Classic Dilemma,” Journal of Democracy 9(1): 27-34.
Przeworski, Adam and Fernando Limongi. 1997. “Modernization: Theories and Facts,” World Politics 49: 155-183.
Rowen, Henry. 1996. “The Short March: China’s Road to Democracy,” The National Interest 45: 61-70.
Scalapono, Robert A. 1998. “Current Trends and Future Prospects,” Journal of Democracy 9(1): 35-41.
Slay, Ben. 1994. ”Rapid versus Gradual Economic Transition,” RFE/RL Research Report, vol. 3, no. 31, pp. 31-42.
Tsai, Kellee. 2005. “Capitalists without a Class,” Comparative Political Studies 38(9): 1130-1158.
Tsui, Kai-Yuen & You-Quian Wang. 2004. “Between Separate Stoves and A Single Menu: Fiscal Decentralization in China,” The China Quarterly, no.177, pp.71-90.
Waldron, Arthur. 1998. “The End of Communism,” Journal of Democracy 9(1): 41-47.
White, Gordon. 1994. “Democratization and Economic Reform in China,” The Austrian Journal of Chinese Affairs 31: 73-92.
Wu, Yongping. 2004. “Rethinking the Taiwan Developmental State,” The China Quarterly 177: 91-114.
Zhao, Suishen. 1998. “Three Scenarios,” Journal of Democracy 9(1): 54-59.
Zheng, Yongnian. 2006. “The Party, Class and Democracy in China,” In Kjeld Erik Brodsgaard and Zheng Yongnian, ed. The Chinese Communist Party in Reform. N.Y.: Routledge. pp. 231-260.
3.Conference Papers
Dickson, Bruce J. 2008. “Who Consents to the ‘Beijing Consensus’? Crony Communism in China,” prepared for presentation at the Conference on “Washington Consensus” versus “Beijing Consensus”: Sustainability of China’s Development Model, May 30-31.
Sachs, Jeffrey D. and Wing Thye Woo. 1997. “Understanding China’s Economic Performance,” Discussion Paper Number 1793, Harvard University, February.
Wu, Yu-Shan. 1994. ”Economic Reform under Different Political Context: Poland and the PRC.” paper presented at the annual meeting of the International Studies Association, Washington, D.C., March 28-April 1.
Wu, Yu-Shan. 2002. ”Economic Development and Political Stability under Authoritarian Regime: China in the 1990’s.” paper presented at the Conference on the Political Reforms of Mainland China in a Changing Global Society, National Taiwan University, Taipei, April 25-27.
 
 
 
 
第一頁 上一頁 下一頁 最後一頁 top
:::
無相關著作
 
QR Code
QRCODE