:::

詳目顯示

回上一頁
題名:高速鐵路由台北延伸至宜蘭經濟影響:以可計算一般均衡分析
作者:郭春河
作者(外文):Kuo, Chun-Ho
校院名稱:國立清華大學
系所名稱:經濟學系
指導教授:廖肇寧
學位類別:博士
出版日期:2021
主題關鍵詞:可計算一般均衡模型高速鐵路社會會計矩陣投入產出分析Computable General EquilibriumHigh-Speed RailSocial Accounting MatrixInput-Output Analysis
原始連結:連回原系統網址new window
相關次數:
  • 被引用次數被引用次數:期刊(0) 博士論文(0) 專書(0) 專書論文(0)
  • 排除自我引用排除自我引用:0
  • 共同引用共同引用:0
  • 點閱點閱:0
台灣為平衡城鄉差異並促進東部發展,計畫投資新台幣1,764億元,建造由台北南港至宜蘭的高速鐵路,本文除研究此類大型之公共投資是否對於經濟能產生預期之正面影響外,並建構了一個含17產業部門的台灣地區及宜花東地區社會會計矩陣,作為未來進行宜花東地區政策模擬之分析基礎。本研究以單國靜態一般均衡模型(Computable General Equilibrium, CGE) 的方法進行下列兩種模擬,評估高鐵延伸投資案的直接效果:第一種情境是以高鐵延伸投資案的投資金額對於台灣地區的一般均衡模型進行衝擊,第二種情境是依照高鐵在宜花東生產總值的比例分配投資金額,對宜花東地區一般均衡模型進行衝擊。本研究首先參考國外的資料拆分高鐵投資的成本結構;其次,定義產業別及地區別,再依照產業部門別建構台灣地區及宜花東地區的社會會計矩陣,最後以General Algebraic Modeling System程式平台對CGE模型進行模擬分析。
第一種情境模擬發現,投資案將使國內生產毛額增加新台幣221,052百萬元,增加1.206%,投資乘數為1.682,進口增加新台幣143,996百萬元,增加1.445%,這可能與高鐵主要設備大多仰賴進口有關,表示在高鐵建設時,若能加強技術移轉,對於經濟發展應有幫助。另外,台灣所有產業的產值都會增加,其中以營建部門增加5.74%最多,增加金額為新台幣94,162百萬元,其次為金屬部門增加3.44%,增加金額為新台幣90,275百萬元。第二種情境顯示該案對宜花東地區之國內生產毛額增加新台幣3,080百萬元,增加1.111%,投資乘數為1.2,宜花東地區所有產業的產值亦都會增加,以營建部門增加5.1%最多,增加金額為新台幣2,446百萬元,其次為金屬部門增加3.62%,增加金額為新台幣581百萬元,運輸部門及住宿部門雖然都沒有新增投資,但其產值分別增加了新台幣197百萬元及新台幣308百萬元,顯見延伸案投資對於地區旅遊有促進作用。儘管如此,上述兩種情境皆顯示該案產生的投資乘數都不大,代表擴大政府公共投資支出用以促進經濟成長的直接效果有限,但此交通建設投資應仍能對促進東西均衡發展及改善區域交通發揮一定影響力。
In order to lower the gap between urban and rural areas and promote eastern Taiwan development, the government plans to invest NT$176.4 billion to extend the high-speed railway from Taipei’s Nangang to Yilan. This article examines whether such large-scale public investment can have the expected impacts on the economy. In addition, the study contributes the current literatures by creating a social accounting matrix (SAM) of Taiwan and Eastern Taiwan with 17 sectors that can serve as the database for analyzing government development policies related to Eastern Taiwan. This research uses the single-country static computable general equilibrium (CGE) model to conduct the following two simulations to evaluate the direct effects of the high-speed rail extension investment. Scenario 1 simulates the impact of the extension investment on the overall economic performance in Taiwan. Scenario 2 focuses mainly on the economic impact of the investment on Eastern Taiwan. To accomplish the goals, we firstly refer to foreign data to disassemble the cost structure of high-speed rail investment; secondly, define the industry sectors and geographic areas, and then construct the social accounting matrix of Taiwan and Eastern Taiwan according to the industry sectors, and finally use the General Algebraic Modeling System program platform to simulate and analyze the CGE model.
The simulation results for scenario 1 show that the investment will increase the gross domestic production by 1.206% to the total of NT$221,052 million. The investment multiplier in this case is 1.682. The import will increase by 1.445% to NT$143,996 million. Since the main high-speed rail equipment relies on imports, it implies that such investment should be more helpful to our economic development if some technology transfers would occur during the construction process. In addition, the output value of all industries in Taiwan will increase, of which the construction sector increased by 5.74% the most, with an increase of NT$94,162 million, followed by the metal sector with an increase of 3.44%, with an increase of NT$90,275 million. Scenario 2 indicates that the investment will increase the gross domestic product of Eastern Taiwan by 1.111% to the total of NT$3,080 million and the investment multiplier is 1.2. The output value of all industries in Eastern Taiwan will also increase. The 5.1% increase in the construction sector is the highest, followed by the metal sector with an increase of 3.62%. The output value of these two sectors will increase to NT$2,446 million and NT$581 million, respectively. Although there is no new investment in the transportation sector and the accommodation sector, their output values increase by NT$197 million and NT$308 million in scenario 2. It means that the investment will promote regional tourism. The above two scenarios show that the investment multipliers generated by the extension investment are not large. Therefore, we can conclude that the direct effect of expanding government public expenditure for promoting economic growth is limited. Nevertheless, the investment should still be able to balance the economic development and improve the traffic condition within different regions in Taiwan.
王娟、孔玉生(2013)。中國與其他金磚四國貿易的引力模型,中國流通經濟,2013(2), 57-60
王塗發、楊浩彥、林幸君、賴金端(2020)。投入產出分析理論與實務,台灣經濟研究院。
江奇晉(1996)。空氣污染防制政策對我國經濟之影響〔未發表之碩士論文〕,淡江大學產業經濟學系。
台灣世曦工程顧問公司(2021)。高鐵延伸屏東新闢路線可行性研究報告,交通部鐵道局委託。
行政院主計總處(2019)。產業關聯表部門分類105年。
行政院主計總處(2019)。統計專區工業及服務業普查統計表,105年地區別統計表,https://www.stat.gov.tw/ct.asp?xItem=44663&ctNode=543
行政院主計總處(2019)。中華民國統計資訊網,國民所得及經濟成長統計資料庫,國內各業生產國內各業生產及平減指數 http://statdb.dgbas.gov.tw/pxweb/Dialog/NI.asp?mp=4
行政院主計處(2019)。105年工業及服務業普查報告。
行政院主計處(2020)。105年產業關聯表。
行政院主計處(2020)。108年家庭收支調查。
行政院主計處(2021)。中華民國統計資訊網104年農林漁牧業普查統計資料查詢系統。
交通部鐵道局,計畫介紹,https://www.rb.gov.tw/showpage.php?lmenuid=3&smenuid=68&tmenuid=93&pagetype=0
李秉正、張其祿,李慧琳(2010)。擴大政府公共投資支出之經濟成長方案是否依然有效?我國新十大建設的可計算一般均衡分析。台灣經濟預測與政策,40(2),122-159。
林幸君、高慈敏(2008)。蘇花國道興建期及通車後之區域經濟效果分析。台灣經濟預測與政策,38(2),31-72。
林建山(2007)。高鐵通車對台灣經濟活動之影響,環球經濟社。
洪德生(2000)。水資源總體經濟模型(四之一),台灣經濟研究院。
洪德生(2007)。後高鐵時代區域均衡發展政策,台灣經濟研究院。
徐世勳、李慧琳、李秉正、黃宗煌(1998)。提升能源使用效率之二氧化碳排放減量效果及其經濟影響評估,台灣經濟學會年會論文集,273-315 頁。
徐世勳、林國榮、蘇漢邦、彭開瓊(2000)。台灣加入 WTO 對溫室氣體減量及產業經濟之影響評估,溫室氣體減量對產業及總體經濟之影響說明會論文集。
婁峰(2015)。中國經濟–能源–環境–稅收動態可計算一般均衡模型理論及應用,中國社會科學出版社。
張欣(2017)。可計算一般均衡模型的基本原理與編程,格致出版社
黃宗煌、李堅明、于眾峰(2010)。CGE模型之最新發展,「綠色能源產業發展與TaiSEND模型運用」教育訊練課程
黃宗煌、李秉正、徐世勳、林師模、劉錦龍,1999。溫室氣體減量成本效益分析–TAIGEM模型建構暨減量策略之經濟評估,行政院環境保護署委託計畫,EPA-88-FA31-03-0006。
黃科智(2012)。石化產業投資對台灣的經濟影響–以國光石化為例〔未發表之碩士論文〕,東吳大學經濟學系碩士論文。
楊晴雯(2012)。能源效率與部門減量成本分析:動態CGE模型的建置與應用〔未發表之博士論文〕,國立中央大學產業經濟研究所。
曾瓊瑤、徐世勳(2000)。台灣課徵探稅之雙紅利效果評估,溫室氣體減量對產業及總體經濟之影響說明會論文集。
趙永、王勁峰(2008)。CGE模型與應用,中國經濟出版社。
劉春初(2005)。區域性可計算一般均衡模型之建立與應用研究-以南部區域為例〔未發表之博士論文〕,國立成功大學資源工程學系。
經濟建設委員會綜合計畫處,1990,台灣可計算一般均衡模型之研究 - 九部門實質面與金融面模型,自由中國之工業。
廖述誼、陳家榮(1996)。臺灣地區水泥供給結構變動對整體經濟影響研究, 台灣銀行季刊,47(4),191-230。
郭訓德(2006)。花蓮觀光休閒產業發展對東部區域經濟的影響研究 – 區域性可計算一般均衡模型(RCGE)分析〔未發表之博士論文〕,成功大學資源工程學系。
歐杰、宋迪、周楠燕(2014)。中國高速鐵路:建設成本分析,中國交通運輸系列專題之九。
賴金端(1997)。石化業污染防制投資的經濟影響分析 - CGE 模型之應用〔未發表之博士論文〕,國立中興大學經濟研究所。
Alonso, W. (1964). Location and Land Use: Toward a General Theory of Land Rent. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, Massachusetts.
Arndt, C., Robinson, S. & Tarp, F. (2002). Parameter estimation for a computable general equilibrium model: a maximum entropy approach, Economic Modelling, 19, 375-398.
Arrow, K.J. & Debreu, G. (1954). Existence of an Equilibrium for a Competitive Economy, Econometrica, 22(3), 265-290
Berck, P., Golan, E., Smith, B., Bamhart, L. & Dabalen, A. (1996). Dynamic revenue analysis for California, California Department of Finance, Sacramento, CA.
Berck, P., Robinson, S. & Goldman, G. (1991). The use of computable general equilibrium models to assess water policies. The Economics and Management of Water and Drainage in Agriculture, (pp. 489-509), Springer US.
Bom, P.R. (2019). Fiscal rules and the intergenerational welfare effects of public investment. Economic Modelling, 81, 455-470.
Borges, A.M. (1986). Applied general equilibrium models: an assessment of their usefulness for policy analysis. OECD journal: economic studies, 7, 7-43.
Bröcker, J. & Mercenier, J. (2011). General Equilibrium Models for Transportation Economic Palma, A.D., Lindsey, R., Quinet, E. & Vickerman, R. (Eds.). A Handbook of Transport Economics, pp. 21-45. Edward Elgar Publishing, Cheltenham, UK.
Buckley, P. H. (1992). A transportation-oriented interregional computable general equilibrium model of the United States. The Annals of Regional Science, 26, 331-348.
Burniaux, J.M., Nicoletti, G. & Oliveria-Martinas, J. (1992). GREEN: A Global Model for Quantifying the Costs of Curbing CO2 Emissions. OECD Economics Studies, 1992(19), 49-90.
Chen, Z., Xue, J., Rose, A.Z. & Haynes, K.E. (2016). The impact of high-speed rail investment on economic and environmental change in China: A dynamic CGE analysis. Transportation Research Part A, 92(2016), 232-245.
Conrad, K. & Schroder, M., 1993. Choosing environmental policy instruments using general equilibrium models. Journal of Policy Modeling 15, 521-543.
Corong, E., Dacuycuy, L., Reyes, R., & Taningco, A. (2013). The growth and distributive impacts of public infrastructure investment in Philippines. In Infrastructure and Economic Growth in Asia (pp. 47-86). Springer Cham.
Despotakis, K. A. & Fisher, A.C. (1988). Energy in a regional economy: A computable general equilibrium model for California. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 15(3), 313-330.
Gazel, R. (1996). Free trade agreements and interregional labor migration: The case of the U.S. and Canada. Annals of Regional Science, 30, 373-390.
Gazel, R., Hewings, G. J. D. & Sonis M. (1995). Trade, sensitivity and feedbacks: Interregional impacts of the US-Canada Free Trade Agreement. In Recent advances in spatial equilibrium modelling, Chapter 14 in Recent Advances in Spatial Equilibrium Modelling, 1996, pp 278-300, Springer.
General Equilibrium Theory. (2021, March 21) in Wikipedia.
https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/General_equilibrium_theory
Ginés De Rus Mendoza, Francisco Javier Campos Méndez, Philippe Gagnepain, Chris A. Nash, Andreu Ulied Segui, Roger Vickermann, Ignacio M. Barrón de Angoiti. (2009). Economic Analysis of High Speed Rail in Europe. The BBVA Foundation.
Ginsburgh, V. & Robinson. S. (1984). Equilibrium and prices in multisector models. ed. by Syrquin, M., Taylor, L & Westphal, L. Economic Structure and Performance, New York: Academic Press
Harberger, A.C. (1962). The Incidence of the Corporation Income Tax. Journal of Political Economy, 70(3), 215-240.
Harrigan, F. & McGregor, P.G. (1989). Neoclassical and Keynesian perspectives on the regional macroeconomy: A computable general equilibrium approach. Journal of Regional Science ,29, 555-573.
Harrigan, F., McGregor P. G. & Swales J. K. (1996). The system-wide impact on the recipient region of a regional labor subsidy. Oxford Economic Papers, 48, 105-133.
Harrigan, F., McGregor P. G., Swales J. K. & Dourmashkin, N. (1991). The sensitivity of output multipliers to alternative technology and factor market assumptions: A computable general equilibrium analysis. Dewhurst, J. H. L., Jensen, R. C. & Hewings. G. J. D., In Regional input-output modeling. New developments and interpretations. Averbury Press.
Harrigan, F., McGregor P. G., Swales J. K. & Dourmashkin, N. (1992). Imperfect competition in regional labour markets: A computable general equilibrium analysis. Environment and Planning A, 24(10), 1463-1481
Hertel, T. W. (1985). Partial vs. general equilibrium analysis and choice of functional form: Implications for policy modeling. Journal of Policy Modeling, 7, 281-303.
Hertel, T. W. & Mount, T.D. (1985). The pricing of natural resources in a regional economy. Land Economics, 61, 229-243.
Hoffmann, S., Robinson, S. & Subramanian, S. (1996). The role of defense cuts in the California recession: Computable general equilibrium models and interstate factor mobility. Journal of Regional Science, 36, 571-595.
Inomata Satoshi & Okamoto Nobhiro (2021). Institute of Developing Economies Japan External Trade Organization (JETRO). https://www.ide.go.jp/English/Research/Topics/Eco/Io/overview.html
Isard, W., 1951. Interregional and regional input-output analysis: a model of a space-economy. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 33(4), 318-328.
Jones, R., and Whalley, J. (1989). A Canadian regional general equilibrium model and some applications. Journal of Urban Economics, 23, 368-404.
Jones, R., and Whalley, J. (1990). Regional balance sheets of gains and losses from national policies. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 20, 421-435.
Jones, R., Whalley, J. & Wigle, R. (1985). Regional impacts of tariffs in Canada: Preliminary results from a small dimensional numerical general equilibrium model. eds. Piggott, J. & Whalley, J. New developments in applied general equilibrium analysis. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Kilkenny, M. (1993a). Rural/urban effects of terminating farm subsidies. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 75(4), 968-980.
Kilkenny, M. (l993b). Agricultural liberalization in segmented or integrated markets, with scale economies. Journal of Economic Integration, 8(2), 201-218.
Kilkenny, M. (1998). Transport costs and rural development. Journal of Regional Science, 38, 293-312.
Kimbell, L. J. & Harrison, G. W. (1984). General equilibrium analysis of regional fiscal incidence. eds. Scarf, H. & Shoven, J. Applied general equilibrium analysis, New York: Cambridge University Press.
Koh, Y. K., Schreiner, D. F. & Shin, H. (1993). Comparisons of regional fixed price and general equilibrium models. Regional Science Perspectives, 23, 33-80.
Kraybill, D. S., Johnson, T. G. & Orden, D. (1992). Macroeconomic imbalances: A multiregional general equilibrium analysis. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 74(3), 727-736.
Li, P.C., Rose, A. (1995). Global warming policy and the Pennsylvania economy: A computable general equilibrium analysis. Economic System Research, 7(2), 151-171.
Liew, L. H. (1984a). “Tops-down” versus “bottoms-up” approaches to regional modeling. Journal of Policy Modelling, 6, 351- 367.
Liew, L. H. (1984b). A Johansen model for regional analysis. Regional Science and Urban Economics 14(1): 129-146.
McGregor. P. G., Swales, J. K. & Yin, Y. P. (1995). Migration equilibria in regional economies: A multi-period CGE analysis of an improvement in local amenities. van den Bergh, J. C. J. M., Nijkamp, P. & Rietveld, P. Recent advances in spatial equilibrium modelling. Springer.
Miller, M. H., Spencer, J. E. (1977). The static economic effects of the U.K. joining the EEC: A general equilibrium approach. The Review of Economic Studies, 38, 175-208.
Mills, E.S. (1967). An aggregative model of resource allocation in a metropolitan area. The American Economic Review, 57(2), 197-210.
Mitra-Kahn, B.H. (2008). Debunking the Myths of Computable General Equilibrium Model (SCEPA working paper series No. 2008-1). SCHWARTZ CENTER FOR ECONOMIC POLICY ANALYSIS (SCEPA). The New School for Social Research, New York.
Morgan, W., Mutti, J. & Partridge, M. (1989). A regional general equilibrium model of the United States: Tax effects on factor movements and regional production. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 71, 626-635.
Morgan. W., Mutti, J. & Rickman, D. (1996). Tax exporting, regional economic growth, and welfare. Journal of Urban Economics, 39, 131-159.
Muth, R.F. (1969). Cities and Housing: The Spatial Pattern of Urban Residential Land Use. University of Chicago Press.
Mutti, J., Morgan, W. & Partridge, M. (1989). The incidence of regional taxes in a general equilibrium framework. Journal of Public Economics, 39, 83-107.
Norrie, K. H., and Percy, M. B. (1983). Freight rate reform and regional burden: A general equilibrium analysis of Western freight rate proposals. Canadian Journal of Economics, 16, 325-349.
Partridge, M.D. & Rickman, D.S. (1998). Regional Computable General Equilibrium Modeling: A Survey and Critical Appraisal. International Regional Science Review, 21(3), 205-248.
Robson, E.N., Wijayaratna, K.P. & Dixit, V.V. (2018). A review of computable general equilibrium models for transport and their application in appraisal. Transportation Research Part A, 116 (2018), 31-53.
Rickman, D. S. (1992). Estimating the impacts of regional business assistance programs: Alternative closures in a computable general equilibrium model. Regional Science, 71(4), 421- 435
Shoven, J. B., Whalley, J. (1992). Applying general equilibrium. Cambridge University Press.
Shoven, J. B., Whalley, J. (1972). A general equilibrium calculation of the effects of differential taxation of income from capital in the U.S. Journal of Public Economics, 1(3-4), 281-321
Shoven, J.B. (1976). The Incidence and Efficiency Effects of Taxes on Income from Capital, Journal of Political Economy, 84(6), 1261-1283.
Sue Wing, I., Anderson, W.P. & Lakshmanan, T.R. (2007). The Broader Benefits of Transportation Infrastructure (OECD/ITF Joint Transport Research Centre Discussion Papers). Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, Paris.
Thissen, M. (1998). A classification of empirical CGE modelling. Research Report 99C01), University of Groningen, Research Institute SOM (Systems, Organisations and Management).
Tomoki Ishikura (2020). Regional economic effects of transport infrastructure development featuring trade gateway region – asymmetric spatial CGE model approach-, Transportation Research Procedia 48(2020), 1750-1765.
UIC (2020). High speed lines in the world. UIC Passenger Department, update on 27th February, 2020
Varian, H.R. (1992). Microeconomic Analysis, W. W. Norton & Company.
Waters, E., Holland, D. W. & Weber, B. A. (1997). Economic impacts of a property tax limitation: A computable general equilibrium analysis of Oregon’s Measure 5. Land Economics, 73(1), 72-89
West, G. R. (1995). Comparison of input-output, input-output+econometric and computable general equilibrium impact models at the regional level. Economic Systems Research, 7(2), 209-227.
Whalley, J. (1984). Trade Liberalization among Major World Trading Areas. Cambridge, MA: MIT press
Whalley, I., Trela. I. (1986). Regional aspects of confederation. Buffalo: University of Toronto Press.
Wigle, R. M. 1992. Transportation costs in regional models of foreign trade: An application to Canada-U.S. Trade. Journal of Regional Science, 32,185-207.
Young, L.M., Huff, K.M.R., (1997). Free Trade in the Pacific Rim: On What Basis? T.W. Hertel (ed.), Global Trade Analysis: Modeling and Applications, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Zhai, F. & Hertel, T. (2005). Impacts of the Doha Development Agenda on China: The Role of Labor Markets and Complementary Education Reforms. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 3702.
 
 
 
 
第一頁 上一頁 下一頁 最後一頁 top
QR Code
QRCODE