:::

詳目顯示

回上一頁
題名:以知識經濟的觀點建構廠商垂直關係上的共演化聯盟模型
作者:洪德芳
作者(外文):Der-Fang Hung
校院名稱:臺灣大學
系所名稱:國際企業學研究所
指導教授:湯明哲
學位類別:博士
出版日期:2012
主題關鍵詞:共演化聯盟策略聯盟聯盟組合治理成本知識複雜度知識範疇經濟機會成本Co-evolution AllianceStrategic AllianceAlliance PortfolioKnowledge ComplexityScope Economy of KnowledgeOpportunism Cost
原始連結:連回原系統網址new window
相關次數:
  • 被引用次數被引用次數:期刊(0) 博士論文(0) 專書(0) 專書論文(0)
  • 排除自我引用排除自我引用:0
  • 共同引用共同引用:0
  • 點閱點閱:62
本研究源起於對知識密集產業(knowledge-intensive industries)的觀察。在這樣的產業中,上游的設備生產廠商會不斷地與下游的設備使用廠商合作開發新的製程設備,學者稱這樣的情況為共演化(co-evolution)現象(Koza & Lewin, 1998; Levinthal & Myatt, 1994; Sturgeon & Lee, 2001; Volberda & Lewin, 2003; Wilson & Hynes, 2009)。然而本研究卻關心一個基本的問題:為什麼共演化的現象會存在於垂直的關係上?依據經濟學家的觀察,共演化所形成的聯盟可能是經濟租(economic rent)的不同來源,如關係租(relational rent)(Dyer & Singh, 1998)。但對策略學者而言,一個共演化的聯盟可能是競爭優勢的不同來源,如鎖喉策略(foreclosure strategy)(Allen, 1971; Hart, Tirole, Carlton, & Williamson, 1990; Rey & Tirole, 2007)。而從知識經濟的觀點來說,共演化聯盟的出現是因為知識屬性所引起的交易成本使然。這些知識的屬性包含:知識的複雜程度(knowledge complexity)、知識的範疇經濟(scope economy of knowledge)、知識的不對稱性(knowledge asymmetry)及知識的不可締約性(knowledge noncontractibility)。由於本研究的興趣在於垂直關係上公司的策略思維,所以定義共演化聯盟為一種合作式的合約安排。在這個安排下,一家公司的知識改變,將會影響另一家公司的知識改變,進而回頭影響第一家公司知識的再改變,並隨著時間周而復始。
既然共演化聯盟是公司的策略選擇,必然也遵循利潤極大化的策略選擇原則。再者,共演化聯盟是一種混合式的治理模式(hybrid governance mode)。是故,要證明共演化聯盟在某些條件下是最適的治理模式,得比較不同治理模式下其治理成本的高低,愈低者,代表其治理的模式愈是最佳的選擇。Williamson (1991)認為治理的模式主要可區分成:市場(market)、組織(organization)與混合模式(hybrid)。而在混合模式中,本研究再進一步區分成:策略聯盟(strategic alliance)、聯盟組合(alliance portfolio)與共演化聯盟(co-evolution alliance)等三種治理模式。在治理成本上,本研究認為在知識密集的產業中,治理成本應包含:知識複雜程度所帶來的成本增加、知識範疇經濟所帶來的成本降低、與知識不對稱性和知識不可締約性所帶來的機會成本的增加。因此,本研究提出三個命題:1) 當知識複雜程度愈高時,市場的治理成本將高於組織的治理成本;2) 當知識複雜程度愈高時,組織的治理成本將高於混合模式的治理成本;3) 在考量機會成本下,當知識的複雜程度愈高,共演化聯盟的治理成本將低於策略聯盟與聯盟組合的治理成本。
在論述上,本研究先行探討垂直整合(如:組織治理模式)與垂直控制(如:市場或混合治理模式)的差異。其中,最大的差異就是交易成本的不同(Chen & Hylton, 1998; Mahoney, 1992)。若沒有交易成本,則垂直整合與垂直控制並無不同。但事實上,交易成本無所不在。而在知識密集的產業中,知識屬性所引起的交易成本,更是影響深遠。
知識,Fransman (1998)稱之為:經過處理的資訊,具有內隱性與情境相依的本質。它具有許多屬性,其中最重要的有:知識複雜程性、知識的範疇經濟性、知識的不對稱性與知識的不可締約性。知識的複雜性源自於知識的互動性,若知識的存取不需透過知識擁有者間的任何互動時,則稱此知識的複雜程度為零。知識的範疇經濟源自於知識不會減少的特性,運用於愈多的不同領域中,對知識的掌握與使用的成本會相對降低。知識的不對稱性源自於知識的多樣性,使得每個人所擁有的知識不必然一樣,而形成不對稱性。知識的不可締約性源自於知識的內隱性,無法於合約上將知識的運用細節描述清楚。本研究利用Cobb-Douglas生產函數,將這四個知識的屬性所引起的成本增減,整合成一個知識成本函數(如下),再利用此函數,找出不同治理模式的成本。最後,再比較不同治理模式的成本高低,證明本研究先前所提出的三個命題。

首先,本研究將市場的治理成本除以公司的治理成本,若比值大於1,則代表市場的治理成本大於公司的治理成本;反之,則市場的治理成本小於公司的治理成本。結果,市場的治理成本大於公司的治理成本,支持本研究的第一個命題。

再者,本研究將公司的治理成本除以混合模式的治理成本,若比值大於1,則代表公司的治理成本大於混合模式的治理成本;反之,則公司的治理成本小於混合模式的治理成本。結果,公司的治理成本大於混合模式的治理成本,支持本研究的第二個命題。

最後,本研究將策略聯盟或聯盟組合的治理成本除以共演化聯盟的治理成本,若比值大於1,則代表策略聯盟或聯盟組合的治理成本大於共演化聯盟的治理成本;反之,則策略聯盟或聯盟組合的治理成本小於共演化聯盟的治理成本。結果,策略聯盟與聯盟組合的治理成本皆大於共演化聯盟的治理成本,支持本研究的第三個命題。


透過三個命題的支持,本研究證明了在知識密集的產業中,隨著知識複雜程度的增加,共演化聯盟將會是最適的治理模式。
This research emerges from a phenomenon which occurs in knowledge-intensive industries where equipment companies collaborate unceasingly with their customers. Scholars refer to it as co-evolution (Koza & Lewin, 1998; Levinthal & Myatt, 1994; Sturgeon & Lee, 2001; Volberda & Lewin, 2003; Wilson & Hynes, 2009). I ask a fundmental question, why the co-evolution phenomenon exists in a vertical relationship. From the viewpoint of economists, a co-evolution alliance could be a different source of economic rent, such as relational rent (Dyer & Singh, 1998). For strategists, a co-evolution alliance could be a different source of competitive advantage, such as foreclosure (Allen, 1971; Hart et al., 1990; Rey & Tirole, 2007). However, from the viewpoint of knowledge economy, the reason why the co-evolution alliance emerges is the transaction cost derived from knowledge characteristics, that is, knowledge complexity, knowledge specialization, knowledge asymmetry and knowledge noncontractibility. This thesis is concerned with the firms’ strategies in a vertical relationship and defines a co-evolution alliance as a cooperative arrangement in which the knowledge change of one firm will influence the knowledge change of its counterparts over time. According to the definition, it is obviously belong to a firm-level study. In addition, this research regards a co-evolution alliance as a strategic choice for a firm pursuing its best performance according to the rule of maximizing profit. Moreover, governance cost in this thesis is viewed as the aggregation of the cost induced by knowledge complexity, the effect contributed by knowledge specialization, and opportunistic cost. Accordingly, how to prove the governance cost of a co-evolution alliance is less than the cost of market and the cost of a firm becomes the core research question. Hence there are three hypotheses which need to be supported. The first hypothesis is that the governance cost of the market is greater than that within a firm under high knowledge complexity. The second hypothesis is that the governance cost within a firm is greater than that of a hybrid mode under high knowledge complexity. The third hypothesis is that considering opportunism cost, the co-evolution alliance is the optimal hybrid mode under high knowledge complexity.
In reasoning, I argue that the relational rent which is proposed by Dyer and Singh (1998) is one of the sources for maximizing profit. But that raises another question: why does a firm not integrate the counterpart if their cooperation is frequent and profitable? The core of this question could be viewed as an issue of vertical control, that is, the decision of trade-off between vertical restraints and vertical integration.
The distinction between vertical restraints and vertical integration is the consideration of transaction costs, in particular contracting costs. Without transaction costs, the advantages that result from vertical integration can be replaced by vertical restraints (Chen & Hylton, 1998; Mahoney, 1992). In fact, transaction costs can be discovered in most of exchange relations and can vary with the characteristics of transacted objects. In knowledge-intensive industries, knowledge is the important resource and the core transacted object. Hence, knowledge characteristics influence the transaction cost and the choice of vertical control mode.
According to Fransman’s (1998) research, knowledge can be defined as processed information with a tacit and context-dependent nature. It has two important characteristics: knowledge complexity and knowledge specialization. Knowledge complexity originates from the interactivity of knowledge (Goldwasser, Micali, & Rackoff, 1985). In other words, knowledge that can be accessed without any interaction has zero complexity (Goldreich & Petrank, 1991). Knowledge specialization, derived from the undiminished feature of knowledge as it is used (Foss, 2005), could be defined as the applied cost of knowledge that is reduced by deploying frequently. Hence, the transaction cost of a firm is related to knowledge complexity and knowledge specialization. The transaction cost will increase as the knowledge complexity is growing; contrarily, the transaction cost will reduce as the knowledge specialization is deepening.

The knowledge cost function can be derived by combining the two transaction costs and the cost of possessed resource into the knowledge production function. As a result, the knowledge cost function has maximum cost when a firm owns two knowledge varieties simultaneously. Furthermore, if the rate of coordination cost of the market to governance cost of a firm is greater than 1, it means that the governance cost of the market is greater than that within a firm. Otherwise, it means the governance cost of the market is less than that within a firm. As a result, the rate is greater than 1 when knowledge complexity gradually increases. Accordingly, this result supports hypothesis 1, which suggested that the coordination cost in the market is greater than that within an organization as knowledge complexity gradually increases.

Similarly, if the rate of coordination cost of a firm to governance cost of a hybrid mode is greater than 1, it means that the governance cost of a firm is greater than that within a hybrid mode. Otherwise, it means the governance cost of a firm is less than that within a hybrid mode. As a result, the governance cost within a firm is greater than that of a hybrid mode as knowledge complexity gradually increases. In other words, a firm is not an optimal governance type when a new production process needs to integrate two different knowledge sets. This implies that cooperative co-specialization has its economic value. Hence, this result supports hypothesis 2, which stated that the governance cost within a firm is greater than that within a hybrid mode as knowledge complexity gradually increases.

Considering only knowledge complexity and knowledge specialization, I directly prove that the hybrid mode is an optimal choice in the case of co-specialization. In the next step, I consider opportunism costs, which stems from knowledge asymmetry and knowledge noncontractibility, and put it into the knowledge cost function to prove that the co-evolution alliance is the optimal governance mode among three hybrid modes: strategic alliance, alliance portfolio and co-evolution alliance. If the same calculative technique is applied, the rate of governance cost of strategic alliance (or alliance portfolio) to governance cost of co-evolution alliance shows that the governance cost of the co-evolution alliance is the least among the three hybrid modes. This result implies that a co-evolution alliance is the optimal governance mode when considering opportunism costs under high knowledge complexity, which supports hypothesis 3.

Abramowitz, M., & Stegun, I. A. 1970. Handbook of Mathematical Functions with Formulas, Graphs, and Mathematical Tables
Aiello, F., & Cardamone, P. 2009. R&D Spillovers and Firms’ Performance in Italy: Evidence from a Flexible Production Function. In G. Arbia, & B. H. Baltagi (Eds.), Spatial Econometrics - Methods and Applications: 143-167. Heidelberg, Germany: Physica-Verlag.
Alchian, A. 1963. Reliability of Progress Curves in Airframe Production. Econometrica, 31(4): 679-693.
Alchian, A. A., & Demsetz, H. 1972. Production, Information Costs, and Economic Organization. The American Economic Review, 62(5): 777-795.
Alchian, A. A., & Demsetz, H. 1973. The Property Right Paradigm. The Journal of Economic History, 33(1): 16-27.
Allee, V. 1993. Reconfiguring the Value Network. Journal of Business Strategy, 21(4): 36-39.
Allen, B. T. 1971. Vertical Integration and Market Foreclosure: The Case of Cement and Concrete. Journal of Law and Economics, 14(1): 251-274.
Alston, L. J., & Mueller, B. 2008. Property Rights and the State. In C. Menard, & M. M. Shirley (Eds.), Handbook of New Institutional Economics: 573-591: Springer Berlin Heidelberg.
Arend, R. J., & Seale, D. A. 2005. Modeling Alliance Activity: An Iterated Prisoners'' Dilemma with Exit Option. Strategic Management Journal, 26(11): 1057-1074.
Argote, L., & Epple, D. 1990. Learning Curves in Manufacturing. Science, 247(4945): 920-924.
Argote, L., & Miron-Spektor, E. 2011. Organizational Learning: From Experience to Knowledge. Organization Science, 22(5): 1123-1137.
Arrow, K. J. 1962. The Economic Implications of Learning by Doing. The Review of Economic Studies, 29(3): 155-173.
Arrow, K. J. 1975. Vertical Integration and Communication. The Bell Journal of Economics, 6(1): 173-183.
ASML, (2012a, July 9), Announcing a Customer Co-Investment Program Aimed at Accelerating Innovation, Netherlands: Advanced Semiconductor Material Lithography Co., Retrieved July 13, 2012, from the World Wide Web: http://www.asml.com/asml/show.do?lang=EN&ctx=5869&rid=46711
ASML, 2012b, ASML Sustainability Report 2011, Nethlands: Advanced Semiconductor Material Lithography Co.
ASML, (2012c, n.d.), Company Profile, Advanced Semiconductor Materials Lithography Co., Retrieved June 3, 2012, from the World Wide Web: http://www.asml.com/asml/show.do?ctx=427
Axelrod, R. 1987. The Evolution of Strategies in the Iterated Prisoner''s Dilemma. In L. D. Davis (Ed.), Genetic Algorithms and Stimulated Annealing 32-41. Los Altos: Morgan Kaufmann.
Axelrod, R., & Dion, D. 1988. The Further Evolution of Cooperation. Science, 242(4884): 1385-1390.
Axelrod, R., & Hamilton, W. 1981. The Evolution of Cooperation. Science, 211(4489): 1390-1396.
Bain, J. S. 1956. Barriers to New Competition: Their Character and Consequences in Manufacturing Industries. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press
Barbour, A. D., Ethier, S. N., & Griffiths, R. C. 2000. A Transition Function Expansion for a Diffusion Model with Selection. The Annals of Applied Probability, 10(1): 123-162.
Barney, J. 1991. Firm Resources and Sustained Competitive Advantage. Journal of Management, 17(1): 99.
Barney, J. B. 1996. The Resource-Based Theory of the Firm. Organization Science, 7(5): 469.
Baum, J. A. C., Calabrese, T., & Silverman, B. S. 2000. Don''t Go It Alone: Alliance Network Composition and Startups'' Performance in Canadian Biotechnology. Strategic Management Journal, 21(3): 267-294.
Belderbos, R., Carree, M., & Lokshin, B. 2004. Cooperative R&D and Firm Performance. Research Policy, 33(10): 1477-1492.
Borys, B., & Jemison, D. B. 1989. Hybrid Arrangements as Strategic Alliances: Theoretical Issues in Organizational Combinations. The Academy of Management Review, 14(2): 234-249.
Bowon, K., & Heungshik, O. 2002. An Effective R&D Performance Measurement System: Survey of Korean R&D Researchers. Omega, 30(1): 19.
Bradford, V. 2011. Semiconductor Device: Fabrication Process. Delhi: The English Press.
Brandenburger, A. 1992. Knowledge and Equilibrium in Games. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 6(4): 83-101.
Bromiley, P. 2005. The Behavioral Foundations of Strategic Management. Malden, USA: Blackwell Publishing.
Brown, J. S., & Vincent, T. L. 1987. Coevolution as an Evolutionary Game. Evolution, 41(1): 66-79.
Brusoni, S., Prencipe, A., & Pavitt, K. 2001. Knowledge Specialization, Organizational Coupling, and the Boundaries of the Firm: Why Do Firms Know More Than They Make? Administrative Science Quarterly, 46(4): 597-621.
Brynjolfsson, E., & Hitt, L. M. 2000. Beyond Computation: Information Technology, Organizational Transformation and Business Performance. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 14(4): 23-48.
Burt, R. S., Jannotta, J. E., & Mahoney, J. T. 1998. Personality Correlates of Structural Holes. Soical Networks, 20: 63-87.
Buzzell, R. D., & Gale, B. T. 1987. The Pims Principles: Linking Strategy to Performance. New York: Free Press.
Buzzell, R. D., Gale, B. T., & Sultan, R. G. M. 1995. Market Share-a Key Profitability. In B. M. Enis, K. K. Cox, & M. P. Mokwa (Eds.), Marketing Classics: 333-345. New Jersey: Prentic-Hall, Inc.
Camerer, C. F. 1991. Does Strategy Research Need Game Theory? Strategic Management Journal, 12(Special Issue: Fundamental Research Issues in Strategy and Economics): 137-152.
Chatterjee, S. 1991. Gains in Vertical Acquisitions and Market Power: Theory and Evidence. The Academy of Management Journal, 34(2): 436-448.
Chatterjee, S., & Harrison, J. S. 2001. Corporate Governance. In M. A. Hitt, R. E. Freeman, & J. S. Harrsion (Eds.), The Blackwell Handbook of Strategic Management, Vol. II: p543-563. Australia: Blackwell Publishing.
Chen, A. C. M., & Hylton, K. N. 1998. Procompetitive Theories of Vertical Control. Hastings Law Journal, 50: 573.
Cheung, S. N. S. 1983. The Contractual Nature of the Firm. Journal of Law & Economics, 26(1): 1-21.
Co, H. C., & Chew, K. S. 1997. Performance and R&D Expenditures in American and Japanese Manufacturing Firms. International Journal of Production Research, 35(12): 3333-3348.
Coase, R. H. 1937. The Nature of the Firm. Economica, 4(16): 386-405.
Coase, R. H. 1960. The Problem of Social Cost. Journal of Law and Economics, 3: 1.
Coccia, M. 2001. A Basic Model for Evaluating R&D Performance: Theory and Application in Italy. R & D Management, 31(4): 453.
Coff, R. 2003. Bidding Wars over R&D-Intensive Firms: Knowledge, Opportunism, and the Market for Corporate Control. The Academy of Management Journal, 46(1): 74-85.
Conner, K. R. 1991. A Historical Comparison of Resource-Based Theory and Five Schools of Thought within Industrial Organization Economics: Do We Have a New Theory of the Firm? Journal of Management, 17(1): 121.
Currall, S. C., & Inkpen, A. C. 2002. A Multilevel Approach to Trust in Joint Ventures. Journal of International Business Studies, 33(3): 479-495.
D''Aveni, R. A., & Ravenscraft, D. J. 1994. Economies of Integration Versus Bureaucracy Costs: Does Vertical Integration Improve Performance? Academy of Management Journal, 37(5): 1167-1206.
Darwen, P. J., & Yao, X. 2002. Co-Evolution in Iterated Prisoner''s Dilemma with Intermediate Levels of Cooperation: Application to Missile Defense. International Journal of Computational Intelligence & Application, 2(1): 83.
Das, T. K., & Teng, B.-S. 1998. Resource and Risk Management in the Strategic Alliance Making Process. Journal of Management, 24(1): 21-42.
Demsetz, H. 1988. The Theory of the Firm Revisited. Journal of Law Economics and Organization, 4(1): 141.
Dierickx, I., & Cool, K. 1989. Asset Stock Accumulation and Sustainability of Competitive Advantage. Management Science, 35(12): 1504-1511.
Diewert, W. E. 1974. Applications of Duality Theory. In M. D. Intriligator, & D. A. Kendrlck (Eds.), Frontiers of Quantitative Economics, Vol. II: 106-199. New York: North-Holland Publishing Company.
Dyer, J. H., & Singh, H. 1998. The Relational View: Cooperative Strategy and Sources of Interorganizational Competitive Advantage. Academy of Management Review, 23(4): 660-679.
Ehrlich, P. R., & Raven, P. H. 1964. Butterflies and Plants: A Study in Coevolution. Evolution, 18(4): 586-608.
Ettlie, J. E. 1998. R&D and Global Manufacturing Performance. Management Science, 44(1): 1.
Farrell, J. 1987. Cheap Talk, Coordination, and Entry. The Rand Journal of Economics, 18(1): 34-39.
Forbes, S. J., & Lederman, M. 2009. Adaptation and Vertical Integration in the Airline Industry. The American Economic Review, 99: 1831-1849.
Foss, N. J. 2005. Strategy, Economic Organization, and the Knowledge Economy: The Coordination of Firms and Resources. New York: Oxford University Press
Fransman, M. 1998. Information, Knowledge, Vision, and Theories of the Firm. In G. Dosi, D. J. Teece, & J. Chytry (Eds.), Technology, Organization, and Competitiveness: Perspectives on Industrial and Corporate Change: 147-193. New York: Oxford University Press.
Fritsch, M. 2002. Measuring the Quality of Regional Innovation Systems: A Knowledge Production Function Approach. International Regional Science Review, 25(1): 86-101.
Galaskiewicz, J. 1985a. Interorganizational Relations. Annual Review of Sociology, 11: 281-304.
Galaskiewicz, J. 1985b. Interorganizational Relations. Annual Review of Sociology, 11(ArticleType: research-article / Full publication date: 1985 / Copyright ¬c 1985 Annual Reviews): 281-304.
Gale, D., & Kariv, S. 2003. Bayesian Learning in Social Networks. Games and Economic Behavior, 45(2): 329-346.
Goldreich, O., & Petrank, E. 1991. Quantifying Knowledge Complexity. Paper presented at the Foundations of Computer Science, 1991. Proceedings., 32nd Annual Symposium on.
Goldwasser, S., Micali, S., & Rackoff, C. 1985. The Knowledge Complexity of Interactive Proof-Systems, Proceedings of the Seventeenth Annual ACM Symposium on Theory of Computing: 291-304. Providence, Rhode Island, United States: ACM.
Gordon, R. J. 2000. Does the "New Economy" Measure up to the Great Inventions of the Past? The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 14(4): 49-74.
Grant, R., & Baden-Fuller, C. 2005. A Knowledge Accessing Theory of Strategic Alliances. Knowledge Management: Critical Perspectives on Business and Management, 41(1): 112.
Grant, R. M. 1996. Toward a Knowledge-Based Theory of the Firm. Strategic Management Journal, 17(Special Issue: Knowledge and the Firm): 109-122.
Griliches, Z. 1979. Issues in Assessing the Contribution of Research and Development to Productivity Growth. The Bell Journal of Economics, 10(1): 92-116.
Grossman, S. J., & Hart, O. D. 1986. The Costs and Benefits of Ownership: A Theory of Vertical and Lateral Integration. Journal of Political Economy, 94(4): 691.
Gulati, R., & Singh, H. 1998. The Architecture of Cooperation: Managing Coordination Costs and Appropriation Concerns in Strategic Alliances. Administrative Science Quarterly, 43(4): 781-814.
Hannan, M. T., & Freeman, J. 1984. Structural Inertia and Organizational Change. American Sociological Review, 49(2): 149-164.
Hart, O., & Moore, J. 2008. Contracts as Reference Points. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 123(1): 1-48.
Hart, O., Tirole, J., Carlton, D. W., & Williamson, O. E. 1990. Vertical Integration and Market Foreclosure. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity. Microeconomics, 1990: 205-286.
Hayek, F. A. 1945. The Use of Knowledge in Society. The American Economic Review, 35(4): 519-530.
Helfat, C. E., & Teece, D. J. 1987. Vertical Integration and Risk Reduction. Journal of Law, Economics, & Organization, 3(1): 47-67.
Helper, S., MacDuffie, J., & Sabel, C. 2000. Pragmatic Collaborations: Advancing Knowledge While Controlling Opportunism. Ind Corp Change, 9(3): 443-488.
Humphrey, A. G. 1985. Antitrust Jurisdiction and Remedies in an Electric Utility Price Squeeze. The University of Chicago Law Review, 52(4): 1090-1118.
Hung, D.-F. 2011. Sustained Competitive Advantage and Organizational Inertia: The Knowledge Economy Perspective, Working.
Ichiishi, T., & Yamazaki, A. 2006. Cooperative Extensions of the Bayesian Game. In S. Kusuoka, & A. Yamazaki (Eds.), Advances in Mathematical Economics, Vol. 8: 273-296: Springer Japan.
Inkpen, A. C. 2001. Strategic Alliances. In M. A. Hitt, R. E. Freeman, & J. S. Harrsion (Eds.), The Blackwell Handbook of Strategic Management, Vol. II: p409-432. Australia: Blackwell Publishing.
Inkpen, A. C., & Currall, S. C. 2004. The Coevolution of Trust, Control, and Learning in Joint Ventures. Organization Science, 15(5): 586-599.
Jackson, M. O., & Yariv, L. 2007. Diffusion of Behavior and Equilibrium Properties in Network Games. The American Economic Review, 97(2): 92-98.
Jensen, M. C., & Meckling, W. H. 1995. Specific and General Knowledge, and Organizational Structure. Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, 8(2): 4-18.
Jones, G. R. 1984. Task Visibility, Free Riding, and Shirking: Explaining the Effect of Structure and Technology on Employee Behavior. The Academy of Management Review, 9(4): 684-695.
Jones, G. R., & Hill, C. W. L. 1988. Transaction Cost Analysis of Strategy-Structure Choice. Strategic Management Journal, 9(2): 159-172.
Jovanovic, B., & Rousseau, P. L. 2002. Moore''s Law and Learning by Doing. Review of Economic Dynamics, 5(2): 346-375.
Kale, P., & Singh, H. 2009. Managing Strategic Alliances: What Do We Know Now, and Where Do We Go from Here? Academy of Management Perspectives, 23(3): 45-62.
Kogut, B., & Zander, U. 1992. Knowledge of the Firm, Combinative Capabilities, and the Replication of Technology. Organization Science, 3(3): 383-397.
Koza, M. P., & Lewin, A. Y. 1998. The Co-Evolution of Strategic Alliances. Organization Science, 9(3): 255-264.
Krattenmaker, T. G., & Salop, S. C. 1986. Anticompetitive Exclusion: Raising Rivals'' Costs to Achieve Power over Price. The Yale Law Journal, 96(2): 209-293.
Lei, D., & Slocum Jr, J. W. 1992. Global Strategy, Competence-Building and Strategic Alliances. California Management Review, 35(1): 81-97.
Levinthal, D., & Myatt, J. 1994. Co-Evolution of Capabilities and Industry: The Evolution of Mutual Fund Processing. Strategic Management Journal, 15: 45-62.
Lopatka, J. E. 1983. Electric Utility Price Squeeze as an Antitrust Cause of Action. UCLA Law Review, 31: 563-606.
Lyons, B. R., & Mehta, J. 1997. Contracts, Opportunism and Trust: Self-Interest and Social Orientation. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 21(2): 239-257.
Macher, J. T. 2006. Technological Development and the Boundaries of the Firm: A Knowledge-Based Examination in Semiconductor Manufacturing. Management Science, 52(6): 826-843.
Macher, J. T., & Mowery, D. C. 2009. Measuring Dynamic Capabilities: Practices and Performance in Semiconductor Manufacturing. British Journal of Management, 20: S41-S62.
Mahoney, J. T. 1992. The Choice of Organizational Form: Vertical Financial Ownership Versus Other Methods of Vertical Integration. Strategic Management Journal, 13(8): 559-584.
Mailath, G. J. 1992. Introduction: Symposium on Evolutionary Game Theory. Journal of Economic Theory, 57(2): 259-277.
McAfee, R. P., & Schwartz, M. 1994. Opportunism in Multilateral Vertical Contracting: Nondiscrimination, Exclusivity, and Uniformity. The American Economic Review, 84(1): 210-230.
McKelvey, R. D., & Palfrey, T. R. 1992. An Experimental Study of the Centipede Game. Econometrica, 60(4): 803-836.
Mertens, J. F., & Zamir, S. 1985. Formulation of Bayesian Analysis for Games with Incomplete Information. International Journal of Game Theory, 14(1): 1-29.
Moulin, H. 2002. An Appraisal of Cooperative Game Theory. In C. Schmidt (Ed.), Game Theory and Economic Analysis: A Quiet Revolution in Economics: 79-94. London: Routledge.
Nelson, R. R., & Winter, S. G. 1982. An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change. Cambridge, Massachusetts: The Belknap Press of Harvard University Press.
Nielsen, R. P. 1988. Cooperative Strategy. Strategic Management Journal, 9(5): 475-492.
Nishiguchi, T. 2001. Coevolution of Interorganizational Relations. In I. Nonaka, & T. Nishiguchi (Eds.), Knowledge Emergence: Social, Technical, and Evolutionary Dimensions of Knowledge Creation: 197-223. New York: Oxford University Press.
Nonaka, I. 1994. A Dynamic Theory of Organizational Knowledge Creation. Organization Science, 5(1): 14-37.
Nonaka, I., Toyama, R., & Nagata, A. 2000. A Firm as a Knowledge-Creating Entity: A New Perspective on the Theory of the Firm. Indusstrial and Corporate Change, 9(1): 1-20.
Norgaard, R. B. 1984. Coevolutionary Development Potential. Land Economics, 60(2): 160-173.
North, D. C. 1990. Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance: Cambridge University Press.
O''Brien, D. P., & Shaffer, G. 1992. Vertical Control with Bilateral Contracts. The Rand Journal of Economics, 23(3): 299-308.
Ordover, J. A., Saloner, G., & Salop, S. C. 1990. Equilibrium Vertical Foreclosure. The American Economic Review, 80(1): 127-142.
Parkhe, A. 1993. Strategic Alliance Structuring: A Game Theoretic and Transaction Cost Examination of Interfirm Cooperation. The Academy of Management Journal, 36(4): 794-829.
Pashigian, B. P. 1968. Limit Price and the Market Share of the Leading Firm. The Journal of Industrial Economics, 16(3): 165-177.
Peppard, J., & Rylander, A. 2006. From Value Chain to Value Network: Insights for Mobile Operators. European Management Journal, 24(2–3): 128-141.
Perry, M. K. 1978. Price Discrimination and Forward Integration. The Bell Journal of Economics, 9(1): 209-217.
Perry, M. K. 1980. Forward Integration by Alcoa: 1888-1930. The Journal of Industrial Economics, 29(1): 37-53.
Peteraf, M. A., & Barney, J. B. 2003. Unraveling the Resource-Based Tangle. Managerial and Decision Economics, 24(4): 309-323.
Plott, C. R. 1989. An Updated Review of Industrial Organization: Applications of Experimental Methods. In R. Schamlensee, & R. D. Willig (Eds.), Handbook of Industrial Organization, Vol. 2: 1111-1167. Oxford: North-Holland.
Polanyi, M. 1966. The Tacit Dimension. London: Routledge & Kegan Paul.
Porter, M. E. 1980a. Competitive Strategy: Techniques for Analyzing Industries and Competitors. New York: Free Press.
Porter, M. E. 1980b. Industry Structure and Competitive Strategy: Keys to Profitability. Financial Analysts Journal, 36(4): 30-41.
Porter, M. E. 1981. The Contributions of Industrial Organization to Strategic Management. Academy of Management Review, 6(4): 609-620.
Porter, M. E. 1985. Competitive Advantage: Creating and Sustaining Superior Performance. New York: Free Press.
Porter, T. B. 2006. Coevolution as a Research Framework for Organizations and the Natural Environment. Organization Environment, 19(4): 479-504.
Powell, W. W., & Snellman, K. 2004. The Knowledge Economy. Annual Review of Sociology, 30(1): 199-220.
Prahalad, C. K., & Bettis, R. A. 1986. The Dominant Logic: A New Linkage between Diversity and Performance. Strategic Management Journal, 7(6): 485-501.
Prahalad, C. K., & Hamel, G. 1990. The Core Competence of the Corporation. Harvard Business Review, 68(3): 79.
Rey, P., & Tirole, J. 2007. A Primer on Foreclosure. In M. Armstrong, & R. Porter (Eds.), Handbook of Industrial Organization, Vol. 3: 2145-2220. Oxford: North-Holland.
Riordan, M. H., & Williamson, O. E. 1985. Asset Specificity and Economic Organization. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 3(4): 365-378.
Ritter, T., & Gemunden, H. G. 2003. Interorganizational Relationships and Networks: An Overview. Journal of Business Research, 56(9): 691-697.
Rotemberg, J. J. 1993. Power in Profit-Maximizing Organizations. Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, 2(2): 165-198.
Rowley, T., Behrens, D., & Krackhardt, D. 2000. Redundant Governance Structures: An Analysis of Structural and Relational Embeddedness in the Steel and Semiconductor Industries. Strategic Management Journal, 21(3): 369-386.
Rumelt, R. 1984. Toward a Strategic Theory of the Firm. In R. B. Lamb (Ed.), Competitive Strategic Mamagement. New York: Prentice-Hall.
Rumelt, R. P. 1991. How Much Does Industry Matter? Strategic Management Journal, 12(3): 167-185.
Rumelt, R. P., Schendel, D., & Teece, D. J. 1991. Strategic Management and Economics. Strategic Management Journal, 12(Special Issue: Fundamental Research Issues in Strategy and Economics): 5-29.
Salinger, M. A. 1988. Vertical Mergers and Market Foreclosure. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 103(2): 345-356.
Salop, S. C., & Scheffman, D. T. 1983. Raising Rivals'' Costs. The American Economic Review, 73(2): 267-271.
Salop, S. C., & Scheffman, D. T. 1987. Cost-Raising Strategies. The Journal of Industrial Economics, 36(1): 19-34.
Silberberge, E., & Suen, W. 2001. The Structure of Economics: A Mathematical Analysis. New York: Irwin McGraw-Hill.
Simon, H. A. 1997a. Administrative Behavior (4th ed.). New York: Macmillan.
Simon, H. A. 1997b. An Empirically Based Microeconomics. London: Cambridge University Press.
Skaggs, B. C., & Huffman, T. R. 2003. A Customer Interaction Approach to Strategy and Production Complexity Alignment in Service Firms. The Academy of Management Journal, 46(6): 775-786.
Spence, A. M. 1981. The Learning Curve and Competition. The Bell Journal of Economics, 12(1): 49-70.
Stabell, C. B., & Fjeldstad, O. D. 1998. Configuring Value for Competitive Advantage: On Chains, Shops, and Networks. Strategic Management Journal, 19(5): 413-413.
Sturgeon, T. J., & Lee, J.-R. 2001. Industry Co-Evolution and the Rise of a Shared Supply-Base for Electronics Manufacturing. Paper presented at the Nelson and Winter Conference, Aalborg, Denmark.
Teece, D. J., Pisano, G., & Shuen, A. 1997. Dynamic Capabilities and Strategic Management. Strategic Management Journal, 18(7): 509-533.
The Economist, (2012, July 14), Chipping In: A Deal to Keep Moore'' Law Alike, New York: The Economist Newpaper Limited, Retrieved July 15, 2012, from the World Wide Web: http://www.economist.com/node/21558628
TSMC, (2012), Company Profile, Hsin-Chu, Taiwan: Taiwan Semiconductor Manufacturing Company Ltd., Retrieved June 1, 2012, from the World Wide Web: http://www.tsmc.com/english/aboutTSMC/company_profile.htm
van den Bergh, J. C. J. M., & Stagl, S. 2003. Coevolution of Economic Behaviour and Institutions: Towards a Theory of Institutional Change. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 13(3): 289.
Volberda, H. W., & Lewin, A. Y. 2003. Co-Evolutionary Dynamics within and between Firms: From Evolution to Co-Evolution. Journal of Management Studies, 40(8): 2111-2136.
Walker, G. 1988. Strategic Sourcing, Vertical Integration, and Transaction Costs. Interfaces, 18(3): 62-73.
Walker, G., & Weber, D. 1984. A Transaction Cost Approach to Make-or-Buy Decisions. Administrative Science Quarterly, 29(3): 373-391.
Wassmer, U. 2010. Alliance Portfolios: A Review and Research Agenda. Journal of Management, 36(1): 141-171.
Wernerfelt, B. 1984. A Resource-Based View of the Firm. Strategic Management Journal, 5(2): 171-180.
Whinston, M. D. 1990. Tying, Foreclosure, and Exclusion. The American Economic Review, 80(4): 837-859.
Williamson, O. E. 1971. The Vertical Integration of Production: Market Failure Considerations. The American Economic Review, 61(2): 112-123.
Williamson, O. E. 1979. Transaction-Cost Economics: The Governance of Contractual Relations. Journal of Law and Economics, 22(2): 233-261.
Williamson, O. E. 1981. The Economics of Organization: The Transaction Cost Approach. American Journal of Sociology, 87(3): 548-577.
Williamson, O. E. 1985. The Economic Institutions of Capitalism. New York: The Free Press.
Williamson, O. E. 1989. Transaction Cost Economics. In R. Schamlensee, & R. D. Willig (Eds.), Handbook of Industrial Organization, Vol. 1: 55-87. Oxford: North-Holland.
Williamson, O. E. 1991. Comparative Economic Organization: The Analysis of Discrete Structural Alternatives. Administrative Science Quarterly, 36(2): 269-296.
Williamson, O. E. 1993. Calculativeness, Trust, and Economic Organization. Journal of Law and Economics, 36(1): 453-486.
Williamson, O. E. 2005. Hierarchies, Markets and Power in the Economy: An Economic Perspective. In G. Dosi, D. J. Teece, & J. Chytry (Eds.), Understanding Industrial and Corporate Change: p109~136. New York: Oxford University Press.
Wilson, J., & Hynes, N. 2009. Co-Evolution of Firms and Strategic Alliances: Theory and Empirical Evidence. Technological Forecasting and Social Change, 76(5): 620-628.
Wong, S.-S. 2008. Task Knowledge Overlap and Knowledge Variety: The Role of Advice Network Structures and Impact on Group Effectiveness. Journal of Organizational Behavior, 29(5): 591-614.
Woodruff, C. 2002. Non-Contractible Investments and Vertical Integration in the Mexican Footwear Industry. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 20(8): 1197-1224.
Wright, T. 1936. Learning Curve. Journal of the Aeronautical Sciences, 3(1): 122-128.
Zajac, E. J., & Olsen, C. P. 1993. From Transaction Cost to Transaction Value Analysis: Implications for the Study Interorganizational Strategies. Journal of Management Studies, 30(1): 131.
Zellner, A., Kmenta, J., & Dreze, J. 1966. Specification and Estimation of Cobb-Douglas Production Function Models. Econometrica, 34(4): 784-795.


 
 
 
 
第一頁 上一頁 下一頁 最後一頁 top