:::

詳目顯示

回上一頁
題名:資本技術互補經濟體系下的租稅政策
作者:俞欣榮
作者(外文):Hsin-Jung Yu
校院名稱:臺灣大學
系所名稱:經濟學研究所
指導教授:楊建成
學位類別:博士
出版日期:2015
主題關鍵詞:資本技術互補工資不均技術進步資訊不對稱最適租稅Capital-Skill complementaritywage inequalitytechnological changeincomplete informationoptimal taxation
原始連結:連回原系統網址new window
相關次數:
  • 被引用次數被引用次數:期刊(0) 博士論文(0) 專書(0) 專書論文(0)
  • 排除自我引用排除自我引用:0
  • 共同引用共同引用:0
  • 點閱點閱:48
美國的經濟體系自二戰後,資本設備的存量與技術在過去五十年來經歷了快速而顯著的提升。於此同時,由於美國的生產科技具備資本與技術勞工的互補性質,設備的技術進步也同時改變了勞動市場的薪資結構,造成技術勞工與非技術勞工的差距增加,影響了經濟體系的所得分配與社會福利。本篇研究即是討論政府在無法辨別技術與非技術勞動者的前提下,如何設計最適的租稅結構,在極小化賦稅所產生的扭曲前提下,極大化社會的福利。本篇論文首先使用過去的估計方法, 以Gordon (1992) 的結果為基礎,更新並估計資本設備的技術創新;另一方面,我們也使用Current Population Survey 的資料,更新美國技術與非技術勞工的相對平均工資比率。透過Ecstein and Nagypal (2004) 的樣本篩選原則,我們發現技術溢酬(skill premium)自1970年以來不斷呈現上漲的趨勢,並在2008年達到歷史的新高。
在給定上述的估計基礎下,我們使用Mirrlees tax 的租稅設計,計算自1947至2000的動態最適稅率。藉由上述估計出來的結果,我們發現在資本技術互補的經濟體系中,最適的邊際資本設備的稅率與非技術勞動所得的邊際稅率為正,而邊際的技術勞動的稅率為負。其背後的經濟直覺,目的是為了要降低美國經濟體系下的技術溢酬(skill premium)。由於過高的技術溢酬與資本累積將造成嚴重的技術溢酬的差異惡化,進一步影響市場中資訊不對稱的現象,因此對資本設備與非技術勞動者課稅,但對技術勞動者補貼將能有效給予市場的參與者誘因揭露自己的資訊。另一方面,隨著資本設備的生產效率不斷提升,政府必須要在生產效率與訊息接露的互動中進行取捨。我們發現針對資本課稅的負擔比例將隨著技術的創新而遞減;反之,技術勞動者的補貼將減少,但非技術勞動者的課稅將逐漸提高,意味著政府在逐漸提高的技術進步中,逐漸以邊際勞動稅率取代邊際資本稅率。而另一方面,為了降低技術與非技術的稅後所得差異,技術勞動者所面對的定額稅將隨著技術創新而提高,反之非技術勞動者所受到的移轉也會逐漸上升,造成技術勞動者的平均稅率呈現上升的趨勢,而非技術勞動者的平均稅率呈現遞減的現象。我們最後也利用電腦的模擬比較Mirrlees 的租稅政策與現存美國的租稅政策。我們發現:如果政府使用Mirrlees tax來進行所得重分配,則能夠較現存的租稅制度有較高的生產水準與消費水準,同時技術溢酬與消費不均的比例也會顯著下降。
The post-war period has witnessed a secular decline in the relative price of capital equipment and an increase in the equipment to GDP ratio. With capital-skill complementarity, more capital equipment will raise the demand for skilled worker and thus the skill premium, which increases the disparities of economic well-being between skilled and unskilled workers. How should a government set taxes on capital versus labor dynamically in face of the rising inequality across workers? Employing an empirically plausible capital-skill complementarity form of production functions as suggested by Krusell et al. (2000), this paper attempts to answer the question by means of the Mirrlees approach. In particular, the government cannot distinguish between skilled and unskilled workers due to information frictions and needs to design a tax program such that workers will truthfully reveal their types. Under the utilitarian and separable utility function, if the skill premium is larger than one, then only the skilled workers have the incentive to mimic the unskilled workers. A higher skill premium allows the skilled workers to have more leisure time when pretending to be unskilled workers and makes the incentive problem more difficult to deal with. Therefore, the government imposes respectively positive, negative and positive tax rates for capital equipment, skilled and unskilled workers to reduce the wage premium and help resolve the incentive problem. Following the secular decline in the relative price of capital equipment, the efficiency loss from taxing capital equipment rises, and the equilibrium tax rates for capital equipment fall while the equilibrium tax rates for both types of workers rise. Over the whole transitional dynamics, the tax rates for capital equipment, skilled and unskilled workers however remain positive, negative and positive, which indicates the concern for incentive problem dominates the concern for efficiency losses. Finally, relative to the current U.S. fiscal policy, the output level will be higher and the consumption inequality will be lower under our Mirrleesian tax program.
[1] Acemoglu, D., 2002. Technical change, inequality, and the labor market. Journal of Economic Literature 40, 7-72.

[2] Acemoglu, D., Autor, D., 2011. Skills, tasks and technologies: implictions for employment and earnings. In: Ashenfelter, O., Card, D. (Eds.), Handbook of Labor Economics, Vol. 4B. North-Holland, Amsterdam.

[3] Angelopoulos, K., Asimakopoulos, S., Malley., J., 2014. Tax smoothing in a business cycle model with capital-skill complementarity. CESifo Working Paper, No. 4744.

[4] Autor, D.H., Katz, L.F., Kearney, M.S., 2008. Trends in U.S. wge inequality: revising the revisionists. Review of Economics and Statistics 90, 300-323.

[5] Bound, J., Johnson, G., 1992. Changes in the Structure of Wages in the 1980’s: An Evaluation of Alternative Explanations. American Economic Review 82, 371-392.

[6] Chamley, C., 1986. Optimal taxation of capitla income in general equilibrium with infinite lives. Econometrica 54, 607-622.

[7] Chen, B.-L., Lu, C.-H., 2013. Optimal factor tax incidence in two-sector human capitalbased models. Journal of Public Economics 97, 75-94.

[8] Conesa, J.C., Kitao, S., Krueger, D., 2009. Taxing capital? Not a bad idea after all! American Economic Review 99, 25-48.

[9] Cummins, J.G., Violante, G.L., 2002. Investment-specific technical change in the United States (1947-2000): measurement and macroeconomic consequences. Review
of Economic Dynamics 5, 243-284.

[10] Eckstein, Z., Nagypal, E. (2004). “U.S. earnings and employment dynamics 1961–2002: Facts and interpretations”. Mimeo. Northwestern University.

[11] Golosov, M., Tsyvinski, A., Werning, I., 2006. New dynamic public finance: a user’s guide. NBER Macroeconomics Annual 21, 317-363.

[12] Gomme, G., Rupert, P., Theory, measurement and calibration of macroeconomic models. Journal of Monetary Economics 54, 460-497

[13] Gordon, R.J., 1990. The Measurement of Durable Good Prices. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, IL.

[14] Griliches, Z., 1969. Capital-skill complementarity. Review of Economics and Statistics 51, 465-468.

[15] Greenwood, J., Hercowitz, Z., Krusell, P., 1997. “Long-run implications of investment specific technological change”. American Economic Review 87, 342–362.

[16] Hornstein, A., Krusell, P., Violante, G.L., 2005. The effects of technical change on labor market inequalities. In: Aghion, P., Durlauf, S.N., (Eds.), Handbook of Economic Growth, Vol. 1B. North-Holland, Amsterdam.

[17] He, H, Liu, Z., 2008. Investment-specific technological change, skill accumulation, and wage inequality. Review of Economic Dynamics 11, 314-334.

[18] Jones, L.E., Manuelli, R.E., Rossi, P.E., 1997. On the optimal taxation of capital income. Journal of Econoomic Theory 73, 93-117.

[19] He, H, Liu, Z., 2008. Investment-specific technological change, skill accumulation, and wage inequality. Review of Economic Dynamics 11, 314-334.

[20] Judd, K.L., 1985. Redistributive taxation in a simple perfect foresight model. Journal of Public Economics 28, 59-83.

[21] Katz, L.F., Autor, D.H., 1999. Changes in the wage structure and earnings inequality. In: Ashenfelter, O., Card, D. (Eds.), Handbook of Labor Economics, Vol. 3A. North-Holland, Amsterdam.

[22] Kocherlakota, N.R., 2010. The New Dynamic Public Finance. Princeton University Press, Princeton.

[23] Krusell, P., Ohanian, L.E., Rios-Rull J.-V. Violante, G.L., 2000. Capital-skill complementarity and inequality: a macroeconomic analysis. Econometrica 68, 1029-1053.

[24] Mirrlees, J.A., 1971. An exploration in the theory of optimum income taxation. Review of Economic Studies 38, 175-208.

[25] Moulton, Brent R., (2001). The Expanding Role of Hedonic Methods in the Official Statistics of the United States? manuscript, Bureau of Economic Analysis.

[26] Naito, H, 1999. Re-examination of uniform commodity taxes under a non-linear income tax system and its implication for production efficiency. Journal of Public Economics, 71, 165-188.

[27] Stiglitz, J., 1982. Self-selection and Pareto efficient taxation. Journal of Public Economics 17, 213-240.

[28] Werning, Iván, 2007. Optimal fiscal policy with redistribution. The Quaterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 122, No. 3, 925-967.


 
 
 
 
第一頁 上一頁 下一頁 最後一頁 top
QR Code
QRCODE