:::

詳目顯示

回上一頁
題名:集團企業綜效之管理--子公司間交易情境之探討
作者:李雨師 引用關係
校院名稱:國立政治大學
系所名稱:企業管理研究所
指導教授:司徒達賢
于卓民
學位類別:博士
出版日期:2008
主題關鍵詞:集團企業綜效交易情境綜效管理機制business groupsynergycontexts of transactionssynergy mechanism
原始連結:連回原系統網址new window
相關次數:
  • 被引用次數被引用次數:期刊(0) 博士論文(0) 專書(0) 專書論文(0)
  • 排除自我引用排除自我引用:0
  • 共同引用共同引用:0
  • 點閱點閱:26
集團企業是多個子公司的組合,在追求集團整體利益極大化的過程中,可能爲了追求內部資源市場配置,因而犧牲某些子公司的個別利益,或是彼此子公司之間出現交叉補貼的現象。在交叉補貼的動機下,雙方子公司進行交易時,將可能有一方犧牲,而另一方受惠;或是一方受惠較多,一方受惠較少的情形。在此情形下,集團企業爲追求長期利益,應採取何種管理作為以促使子公司間進行交易,是本研究的核心問題。
本研究以集團企業之子公司間交易為主題,嘗試探索影響子公司間交易發生的因素(本研究將影響子公司間交易發生的因素命名為「交易情境」),且以「交易情境」的觀點,進一步探討集團企業中子公司間交易之管理方式。為此,本研究以台灣集團企業作為研究對象,結合集團企業之綜效管理相關理論及文獻,針對實務現象進行分析。
本研究採質性研究方法,以集團企業中子公司間的「交易」為分析單位,進行資料蒐集與個案分析。本研究分二階段進行。第一階段為前導個案研究,依個案分析歸納發現,子公司間交易發生的情境因素包括:「投入可衡量程度」、「投入成本程度」、「市場失靈程度」以及「產出互惠程度」。子公司間交易的管理作為包括:「目標一體化」、「轉撥計價」和「市場機制(市價)」。並且建構子公司間「交易情境」與「管理作為」之配適模式,發展出初步的研究架構、研究發現與研究命題,作為後續個案研究之原樣複現基礎。第二階段為後續個案研究,目的在修正並驗證前一階段建立的研究架構與研究命題,使其內容更為豐富。
本研究整合前導個案與後續個案,歸納出下列研究發現:
一、 公司間交易情境與管理作為之配適模式
集團企業進行子公司間交易管理時,應考量「交易」的本質,也就是交易情境,針對「市場失靈程度」、「投入可衡量程度」、「投入成本程度」以及「產出互惠程度」之不同,選擇較能發揮綜效之管理作為。子公司間交易的管理作為包括「目標一體化」、「轉撥計價」和「市場機制(市價)」,因應不同的交易情境組合,管理作為的搭配組合也有所不同,藉由此配適模式,以追求集團企業之綜效。
二、 「目標一體化」程度之提升,有助於「轉撥計價」、「市場機制(市價)」方式的發揮
集團企業在追求綜效過程中,若需要犧牲某一家子公司,成全另一家子公司利益時,「目標一體化」將扮演重要的角色。透過提升「目標一體化」程度,使「轉撥計價」、「市場機制(市價)」方式更能發揮。換言之,集團企業的綜效是源自於「目標一體化」,「目標一體化」有助於子公司之間交易成本的降低。
三、 「目標一體化」、「轉撥計價」和「市場機制(市價)」的使用有其搭配的強弱程度
「目標一體化」對於「轉撥計價」和「市場機制(市價)」具有調節作用,當子公司間交易依賴「高轉撥計價」時,則使用「目標一體化」的程度較低。當子公司間交易依賴「低轉撥計價」時,則使用「目標一體化」的程度較高。當子公司間交易依賴「市場機制(市價)」時,則使用「目標一體化」的程度較低。
A business group is composed of several subsidiary companies. To increase group-level profits, the profits of subsidiaries may be scarified and one subsidiary may cross-subsidize others. In cross-subsidization between two subsidiaries, one may benefit more than the other or one may benefit and the other may suffer.
Giving this understanding, two-stage study is conducted to observe the phenomena by studying business groups in Taiwan. In the first stage, ten pilot cases are conducted and eight more cases are examined in the second stage. Taking the view of “the contexts of transactions”, this study aims to examine how headquarters manages inter-subsidiaries transactions to create group synergy.
As part of the methodology, a qualitative research method is adopted and the unit of analysis is inter-subsidiaries transaction. The research process includes two stages. In the first stage, it is found that the contexts affecting inter-subsidiaries transactions consist of “level of input measurability”, “level of input cost”, “level of market failure” and “level of outcome reciprocity”. The mechanisms for managing inter-subsidiaries transactions include “goal alignment”, “transfer-pricing” and “market mechanism (market price)”. Further, a fitting model between “the context of transactions” and “mechanisms” is proposed as a prior research framework for the second stage.
In terms of integrating two-stage case analysis, three main research findings include:
1. A fitting model between “the contexts of transactions” and “mechanisms”
Headquarters should take into account the essence of transaction when managing inter-subsidiaries transactions. The essence of transaction means “level of input measurability”, “level of input cost”, “level of market failure” and “level of outcome reciprocity”. In other words, different mechanisms should be adopted in different contexts of transactions to achieve group synergy.
2. The increase of the level of “goal alignment” is conducive to “transfer-pricing” and “market mechanism (market price)”
“Goal alignment” plays an important role in a business group, especially when the profits of subsidiaries may be scarified and one subsidiary may cross-subsidize others. The increase of the level of “goal alignment” is conducive to “transfer-pricing” and “market mechanism (market price)”. In other words, synergy in a business group results from “goal alignment”, and “goal alignment” decreases the transaction cost between subsidiaries.
3. The combination of three mechanisms with different level
“Goal alignment” has mediating effect for “transfer-pricing” and “market mechanism (market price)”. If headquarters depends on high level of “transfer-pricing”, then the level of “goal alignment” is low. If headquarters depends on low level of “transfer-pricing”, then the level of “goal alignment” is high. If headquarters depends on “market mechanism (market price)”, then the level of “goal alignment” is low.
一、 中文部份
中華徵信所 (2007),台灣地區集團企業研究。台北:中華徵信所。
司徒達賢、于卓民、曾紀幸 (1997),「環境特性與公司特性對多國企業網絡關係之影響---在台外商公司之實證研究」,管理學報,14(2):155-176。new window
司徒達賢 (2005),策略管理新論:觀念架構與分析方法。台北:智勝文化出版社。new window
司徒達賢 (2006),整合的智慧。台北:天下雜誌出版社。
朱文儀、莊正民 (1999),「Decision-making autonomy and divisional effectiveness in multibusiness firms: From contingency perspective to cultural control perspective」,亞太管理評論,4(4):345-356。
任慶宗 (2003),「集團企業子公司之綜效利益與彈性限制---網絡觀點」,國立政治大學企業管理學系未出版之博士論文。new window
邱志聖 (2006),策略行銷分析:架構與實務應用,第二版,智勝文化出版社。
施振榮 (1996),再造宏碁。台北:天下文化。
葉重新 (2001),教育研究法。台北:心理出版社。
蕭瑞麟 (2006),不用數字的研究。台北:台灣培生教育。
二、 英文部份
Adler, P. S. and S-W Kwon (2002), “Social capital: Prospects for a new concept,” Academy of Management Review, 27(1): 17-40.
Ansoff, H. (1965), Corporate Strategy, NY: McGraw-Hill Book.
Barnard, C. (1938), The Fuctions of the Executive, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Barney, J. (1991), “Firm resources and sustained competitive advantage,” Journal of Management, 17(1): 99-120.
Bartlett, C.A. and S. Ghoshal (1993), “Beyond the m-form: Toward a managerial theory of the firm,” Strategic Management Journal, 14(special issue): 23-46.
Besanko, D., D.Dranove, and M. Shanley (2000), Economics of Strategy, 2nd ed, NY: Wiley.
Birkinshaw, J. and M. Lingblad (2005), “Intrafirm competition and charter evolution in the multibusiness firm,” Organization Science, 16(6): 674-686.
Blau, P. (1964), Exchange and Power in Social Life, NY: Wiley.
Bock, G. W., R. W. Zmud, Y. G. Kim, and J. N. Lee (2005), “Behavioral intention formation in knowledge sharing: Examine the roles of extrinsic motivators, social-psychological forces, and organizational climate,” MIS Quarterly, 29(1): 87-111.
Burt, R. S. (1992), “The social structure of competition,” in Nohira, N. and R. Eccles(ed.), Networks and Organizations: Structure, Form, and Action, Boston: Harvard Business School Press.
Campbell, A., M. Goold, and M. Alexander (1995), “The value of the parent company,” California Management Review, 38(1): 79-97.
Caves, R. and M. Uekusa (1976), Industrial Organization in Japan, Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.
Chandler, A. D., Jr. (1962), Strategy and Structure: Chapters in the history of the Industrial Enterprise, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Chang, S. and J. Hong (2000), “Economic performance of the Korean business group: Intra-group resource sharing and internal business transaction,” Academy of Management Journal, 43(3): 429-448.
Chang, S. J. and U. Choi (1988), “Strategy, structure and performance of Korean business groups: A transaction cost approach,” Journal of Industrial Economics, 37(2): 141-159.
Chatterjee, S. and B. Wernerfelt (1991), “The link between resources and types of diversification: theory and evidence,” Strategic Management Journal, 12(1): 33-48.
Cheng, J. L. C. and W. Mckinley (1983), “Toward an integration of organization research and practice: A contingency study of bureaucratic control and performance in scientific settings,”Administrative Science Quarterly, 28(1): 85-100.
Chiu, C. M., M. H. Hsu, and T. G. Wang (2006), “Understanding knowledge sharing in virtual communities: An integration of social capital and social cognitive theories,” Decision Support Systems, 42(3): 1872-1888.
Cialdini, R. B. (1988), Influence: Science and Practice, 2nd ed, Glenview, IL: Scott, Foresman.
Cialdini, R. B., B. L. Green, and A. J. Rusch (1992) “When tactical pronouncements of change becomes real change: The case of reciprocal persuasion,” Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 63(1): 30-40.
Coleman, J. S. (1990), Foundation of Social Theory, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Corning, P. (1998), “The synergism hypothesis,” Journal of Social and Evolutionary Systems, 21(2): 133-172.
Corning, P. (2002), “ “Devolution” as an opportunity to test the“synergism hypothesis”and a cybernetic theory of political systems,” Systems Research and Behavioral Science, 19(1): 3-26.new window
Davis, R. and L. G. Thomas (1993), “Direct estimation of synergy: A new approach to the diversity-performance debate,” Management Science, 39(11): 1334-1346.
DiMaggio, P. J. and W. P. Powell (1983), “The iron cage revisted: Institutional isomorphism and collective rationality in organizational fields,” American Sociological Review, 48(2): 147-160.
Dutta, S. (1997), Family business in India, New Delhi: Response Books/Sage.
Eisenhardt, K. M. (1985), “Control: Organizational and economic approaches,” Management Science, 31(2): 134-149.
Eisenhardt, K. M. (1989), “Agency theory: assessment and review,” Academy of Management Journal, 14(1): 57-74.
Eisenhardt, K. M. and D. C. Gulunic (2000), “Coevolving: At last, a way to make synergies work,” Harvard Business Review,78(1): 91-101.
Farjoun, M. (1994), “Beyond industry boundaries: human expertise, diversification and resource-relater industry groups,” Organization Science, 5(2): 185-199.
Finkelstein, S. and D. C. Hambrick (1988), “Chief executive compensation: A synthesis and reconciliation,” Strategic Management Journal, 9(6): 543-558.
Fudenberg, D. and J. Tirole (1985), “Preemption and Rent equalization in the Adoption of New Technology,” Review of Economic Studies, 52(2): 383-402.
Fudenberg, D.and J. Tirole (1986), Dynamic Models of Oligopoly, London: Harwood.
Ferri, S. P., K. A. Kim, and P. Kitsabunnarat (2003), “The cost (and benefit) of diversified business groups: The case of Korean chaebols,” Journal of Banking and Finance, 27(2): 521-273.
Galbraith, J. R. and D. A. Nathanson (1978), Strategy Implementation: The role of structure and process, West, St. Paul, MN.
Geertz, C. (1978), “The bazaar economy: Information and search in peasant marketing,” American Economic Review, 68(2): 28-32.
Gerlach, M. (1992), “The Japanese corporate network: A blockmodel analysis,” Administrative Science Quarterly, 37(1): 105-139.
Ghoshal, S. and C. Bartlett (1990), “The multinational corporation as an inter organizational network,” Academy of Management Review, 15(4): 603-625.
Ghoshal, S., H. Korine, and G. Szulanski (1994), “Interunit communication in multinational corporations,” Management Science, 40(1): 96-110.
Ghoshal, S. and H. Mintzberg (1994),” Diversifiction and diversifact,” California Management Review, 37(1): 8-27.
Ghoshal, S. and P. Moran (1996), “Bad for practice: A critique of the transaction cost theory,” Academy of Management Review, 21(1): 13-47.
Ghoshal, S. and N. Nohria (1989), “Internal differentiation within multinational corporations,” Strategic Management Journal, 10(4): 323-337.
Glaser, B. and A. Strauss (1967), The discovery of grounded theory: Strategies for qualitative research, Chicago, IL: Aldine.
Goold, M. and A. Campbell (1987), “Managing diversify: Strategy and control diversification British companies,” Long Range Planning, 20(5): 42-52.
Goold, M. and A. Campbell (1998a), “Desperately seeking synergy,” Harvard Business Review, 76(5): 130-143.
Goold, M. and A. Campbell (1998b), “Corporate strategy and parenting,” Long Range Planning, 31(2): 308-314.
Goold, M. and A. Campbell (2000), “Taking stock of synergy,” Long Range Planning, 33(1): 72-96.
Goold, M. and K. Luchs (1993), “Why diversify? four decades of management thinking,” Academy of Management Executive, 7(3): 7-25.
Govindarajan, V. (1988), “Contingency Approach to strategy implementation at the business unit : Integrating administrative mechanisms with strategy,” Academy of Management Journal, 31(4): 828-853.
Granovetter, M. (1994), “Business group,” in N. Smelser and R. Swedberg(ed.), The Handbook of Economics Sociology, 453-475. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Grant, R. M. (1996), “Toward a knowledge-based theory of the firm,” Strategic Management Journal, 17(special issue): 109-122.
Gupta, A. K. and V. Govindarajan (1986), “Resource Sharing among SBUs: Strategic Antecedents and Administrative Implications,” Academy of Management Journal, 29(4): 695-714.
Gupta, A. K. and V. Govindarajan (1991), “Knowledge flows and the structure of control within multinational corporations,” Academy of Management Review, 16(4): 768-792.
Gupta, A. K., V. Govindarajan, and A. Malhotra (1999), “Feedback-seeking behavior within multinational corporations,” Strategic Management Journal, 20(3): 205-222.
Harrigan, K. R. (1984), “Formulating vertical integration strategies,” Academy of Management Review, 9(4): 638-652.
Harrigan, K. R. (1985d), Strategic flexibility, MA: Lexington Books, Lexington.
Harrison, J. S., E. H. Jr. Hall and R. Nargundkar (1993), “Resource allocation as an outcropping of strategic consistency: Performance implications,” Academy of Management Journal, 36(5): 1026-1051.
Harrison, J. S., M. A. Hitt, R. E. Hoskisson, and R. D. Ireland (2001), “Resource complementarity in business combinations: Extending the logic to organizational alliances,” Journal of Management, 27(6): 679-690.
Hayes, R. H. and S. C. Wheelwright (1984), Restoring our competitive edge: Competing through manufacturing, NY: Wiley.
Heide, J. B. and A. S. Miner (1992), “The shadows of the future: Effects of anticipated interaction and frequency of contact in buyer-seller cooperation,” Academy of Management Journal, 35(2): 265-291.
Helfat, C. E. and K. M. Eisenhardt (2004), “Inter-temporal economies of scope, organizational modularity, and the dynamics of diversification,” Strategic Management Journal, 25(13): 1217-1232.
Hennart, J. F. (1991), “Control in multinational firms: The role of price and hierarchy,” Management International Review, 31(special issue): 71-96.
Hill, C. W. (1988), “Internal capital market controls and financial performance in multidivisional firms,” Journal of Industrial Economics, 37(1): 67-83.
Hill, C. W., M. A. Hitt, and R. E. Hoskisson (1992), “Cooperative versus competitive structures in related and unrelated diverdified firms,” Organization Science, 3(4): 501-521.
Hill, C. W. and R. E. Hoskisson (1987), “Strategy and structure in the multiproduct firm,” Academy of Management Review, 12(2): 331-341.
Hitt, M. A., Hoskisson, R. E., and R. D. Ireland (1990), “Mergers and acquisitions and managerial commitment to innovation in M-form firms,” Strategic Management Journal, 11(special issue): 29-47.
Homans, G. C. (1950), The Human Group. Harcourt, Brace, and World, New York.
Ilinith, A. Y. and C. P. Zeithaml (1995), “Operationalizing and testing Galbraith’s center of gravity theory,” Strategic Management Journal, 16(5): 401-410.
Ingram, P. and P. W. Roberts (2000), “Friendship among competitors in the Sydney hotel industry,” American Journal of Sociology, 106(2): 387-423.
Iversen, M. (1998), “Competitive advantage through intrafirm synergies,” DRUID Winter Conference.
John, C. H. S.t. and J. S. Harrison (1999), “Manufacturing-based relatedness, synergy, and coordination,” Strategic Management Journal, 20(2):129-145.
Keister, L. A. (1998), “Engineering growth: Business group structure and firm performance in China’s transition economy,” American Journal of Sociology, 104(2): 404-440.
Khanna, T. and K. Palepu (1997), “Why focused strategies may be wrong for emerging markets,” Harvard Business Review, 75(4): 41-51.
Khanna, T. and K. Palepu (1999), “Policy shocks, market intermediaries, and corporate strategy: The evolution of business group in Chile and India,” Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 8(2): 271-310.
Khanna, T. and K. Palepu (2000a), “Is group membership profitable in emerging markets? An analysis of diversified Indian business group,” Journal of Finance, 55(2): 867-891.
Khanna, T. and K. Palepu (2000b), “The future of business groups in emerging markets: Long-run evidence from Chile,” Academy of Management Journal, 43(3): 268-285.
Khanna, T. and J. Rivkin (2001), “Estimating the performance effects of business groups in emerging markets,” Strategic Management Journal, 22(1): 45-74.
Khanna, T. and J. Rivkin (2006), “Interorganizational ties and business group boundaries: Evidence from an emerging economy,” Organization Science, 17(3): 333-352.
Klein, B., R. Crawford, and A. Alchain (1978), “Vertical integration, appropriable rents and competitive contracting process,” Journal of Law and Economics, 21(2): 297-326.
Kogut, B. and U. Zander (1992), “Knowledge of the firm, combinative capability, and the replication of technology,” Organization Scie c , 3(3): 383-397.
Komorita, S. S., C. D. Parks, and G. L. Hulbert (1992), “Reciprocity an the induction of cooperation in social dilemmas,” Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 62(4): 607-617.
Krebs, D. L. (1975), “Empathy and altruism,” Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 32(6): 1134-1146.
Lado, A. A., N. G. Boyd, and S. C. Hanlon (1997), “Competition, cooperation, and the search for economic rents: A syncretic model,” Academy of Management Review, 22(1): 110-141.
Lebas, M. and J. Weigenstein (1986),“Management control: The roles of rules, markets and culture,” Journal of Management Studies, 23(3): 259-272.
Leff, N. (1976), “Capital markets in the less developed countries: The group principal, ” in R. McKinnon(ed.), Money and Finance in Economic Growth and Development, NY: Dekker.
Leff, N. (1978), “Industrial organization and entrepreneurship in the developing countries: The economic groups,” Economic Development and Cultural Change, 26(4): 661-675.
Leonard-Barton, D. and D. K. Shinha (1993), “Developer-user interaction and user satisfaction in interal technology transfer,” Academy of Management Journal, 36(5): 1125-1139.
Levinthal, D. (1988), “A survey of agency models of organizations,” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 9(2):153-185.
Lincoln, J. R., M. L. Gerlach, and C. L. Ahmadjian (1996), “Keiretsu networks and corporate performance in Japan,” American Sociological Review, 61(1): 67-88.
Mahoney, J. T. (1992), “The choice of organizational form: Vertical financial ownership versus other methods of vertical intergration,” Strategic Management Journal, 13(8): 559-584.
Markides, C. C. and Chu, W. (1999), “Autonomy versus strategic control in diversified companies: The management of conflicting strategic imperatives,” Academy of Management 1999 Annual Conference, Chicago, August 6-11.
Markides, C. C. and P. J. Williamson (1994), “Related diversification, core competencies and corporate performance,” Strategic Management Journal, 15(special issue): 149-166.
Markides, C. C. and P. J. Williamson (1996), “Corporate Diversification and Organizational Structure: A Resource-Based View,” Academy of Management Journal, 39(2): 340-367.
Martin, J. and K. M. Eisenhardt (2001), “Cross-business synergy: Sources, processes and the capture of corporate value,” Working paper, Stanford University, California.
Michael, S. C. and J. A. Pearce (2004), “Choosing constrains as a third solution to agency,” Journal of Management Studies, 41(7): 1171-1197.
Milgrom, P. and J. Roberts (1990), “Barganing costs, influence activities, and the organization of economic activity,” J. Sheplse and K. Sheplse, eds. Perspectives in Positive Political Economy. NY: Cambridge University Press.
Milgrom, P. and J. Roberts (1995), “Complementarities and fit: strategy, structure and organizational change in manufacturing,” Journal of Accounting and Economics, 19(2,3): 179-208.
Mizruchi, M. S. (1996), “What do interlocks do? An analysis, critique, and assessment of research on interlocking directorates,” Annual Review of Sociology, 22: 271-298.
Nahapiet, J. and S. Ghoshal (1998), “Social capital, intellectual capital and the organizational advantage,” Academy of Management Review, 23(2): 242-266.
Nakatani, I. (1984), “The economic role of financial corporate grouping,” in M. Aoki(ed.), The economic analysis of the Japanese firm, Amsterdam: North-Holland.
Nohria, N. and S. Ghoshal, (1994), “Differentiated fit and shared value: Alternatives for managing headquarters-subsidiary relationship,” Strategic Management Journal, 15(6): 491-502.
Ouchi, W. G. (1977), “The relationship between organizational structure and organizational control,” Administrative Science Quarterly, 22(1): 95-112.
Ouchi, W. G. (1979), “A conceptual framework for the design of organization control mechanisms,” Management Science, 25(9): 833-848.
Ouchi, W. G. (1980), “Markets, bureaucracies, and clans,” Administrative Science Quarterly, 25(1): 129-145.
Ouchi, W. G. and M. A. Maguire(1975), “Organization control: Two functions,” Administrative Science Quarterly, 20(4): 559-569.
Panzar, J. C. and R.D. Willig (1981), “Economies of scope,” American Economic Review, 71(2): 268-272.
Peng, M. W. and P. S. Heath (1996), “The growth of the firm in planned economies in transition: Institutions, organizations, and strategic choice,” Academy of Management Review, 21(2): 492-528.
Podolny, J. M. (1994), “Market uncertainty and the social character of economic exchange,” Administrative Science Quarterly, 39(3): 458-483.
Podolny, J. M. (1998), “Network forms of organization,” Annual Review of Sociology, 24(1): 57-76.
Porter, M. E. (1985), Competitive Advantage, NY: Free Press.
Portes, A. (1998), “Social capital: Its origins and applications in modern sociology,” Annual Review of Sociology, 24: 1-24.
Powell, W. (1990), “Neither market nor hierarchy: network forms of organizations,” Research in Organizational Behavior, 12: 295-336.
Powell, W. and L. Smith-Doerr (1994), “Networks and economic life,” in N.J. Smelseer and R. Swedberg(ed.), The Handbook of Economic Sociology, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Prahalad, C. K. and R. A. Bettis (1986), “The dominant logic: A new linkage between diversity and performance,” Strategic Management Journal, 7(6): 485-501.
Rondfleisch, A. and J. B. Heide (1997), “Transaction cost analysis: Past, present, and future applications,” Journal of Marketing, 61(4): 30-54.
Robins, J. A. and M. F. Wiersema (1995), “A resource-based approach to the multibusiness firm: Empirical analysis of portfolio interrelationships and corporate financial performance,” Strategic Management Journal, 16(4): 277-299.
Rozemeijer, F. A., A. V. Weele, and M. Weggeman (2003), “Creating corporate advantage through purchasing: Toward a contingency model,” Journal of Supply Chain Management, 39(1): 4-13.
Rumelt, R. P. (1974), Strategy, Structure and Economic Performance, Boston: Harvard Business School Press.
Rutherford, M. A., A. K. Buchholtz, and J. A. Brown (2007), “Examing the relationsips between monitoring and incentives in corporate governance,” Journal of Management Studies, 44(3): 414-430.
Silverman, B. S. (1999), “Technological resources and the direction of the corporate diversification: toward an integration of the resource-based view and transaction cost economics,” Management Science, 45(8): 1109-1124.
John, St. C. H. and L. W. Rue (1991), “Coordinating mechanisms, marketing and manufacturing consensus and marketplace performance,” Strategic Management Journal, 12(7): 549-555.
Stigler, G. J. (1968), The Organization of Industry, Richard D. Irwin, Homewood, IL.
Strauss, A. and J. Corbin (1998), Basics of Qualitative Research: Techniques and Procedures for Developing Grounded Theory, CA: Sage.
Surra, C. A. and M. Longstreth (1990), “Similarity of outcomes, interdependence, and conflict in dating relationships,” Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 59(3): 501-516.
Tanriverdi, H. and N. Venkatraman (2005), “Knowledge relatedness and the performance of multibusiness firms,” Strategic Management Journal, 26(2): 97-119.
Teece, D. J. (1982), “Towards an economic theory of the multiproduct firm,” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 3(1): 39-63.
Thibaut, J. and H. H. Kelley (1959), The Social Psychology of Groups, NY: Wiley.
Thompson, J. D. (1967), Organizations in Action. NY: Mcgraw-Hill.
Tsai, W. (2002), “Social structure of “coopetition”within a multiunit organization: Coordination, competition, and intraorganizational knowledge sharing,” Organization Science, 13(2): 179-190.
Uzzi, B. D. (1996), “The sources and consequences of embeddedness for economic performance of organizations: The network effect,” Administrative Sociological Review, 61(4): 674-698.
Walsh, J. P. and J. K.Seward, (1990), “On the efficiency of internal and external corporate control mechanisms,” Academy of Management Review, 15(3): 421-458.
Williamson, O. E. (1967), “Hierarchical control and optimum firm size,” Journal of Political Economy, 75(2): 123-138.
Williamson, O. E. (1975), Markets and Hierarchies: Analysis and Antitrust Implications, NY: Free Press.
Williamson, O. E. (1985), The Economic Institutions of Capitalism: Firms, Markets, Relational Contracting, NY: Free Press.
Williamson, O. E. (1983), “Credible commitments: Using hostages to support exchange,” American Economic Review, 73(4): 519-540.
Williamson, O. E. (1991), “Comparative economic organization: The analysis of discrete structural alternatives,” Administrative Science Quarterly, 36(2): 269-296.
Williamson, O. E. (2000), “The new institutional economics: Taking stock, looking ahead,” Journal of Economic Literature, 38(3): 595-613.
Yin, R. (1994), Case Study Research: Design and Methods. CA: Sage.
Zeitlin, M. (1974), “Corporate ownership and control: The large corporation and the capitalist class,” American Journal of Sociology, 79: 1073-1119.
 
 
 
 
第一頁 上一頁 下一頁 最後一頁 top
:::
無相關著作
 
無相關點閱
 
QR Code
QRCODE